SlideShare uma empresa Scribd logo
1 de 7
Baixar para ler offline
399© IBFD BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION JULY 2016
The United Kingdom’ s Diverted Profits Tax and
Tax Treaties: An Evaluation
This article examines the diverted profits tax
(DPT) introduced by the United Kingdom to
counter aggressive tax planning adopted by
many multinational enterprises so as to transfer
profits from its jurisdiction, and the main
controversies surrounding the compatibility of
the DPT with tax treaties.
1. Introduction
InApril2015,theUnitedKingdomintroducedthediverted
profits tax (DPT) into its domestic law. The DPT has the
declared objective of countering aggressive tax planning
as used by many multinational enterprises (MNEs) to
transfer profits from the United Kingdom’ s jurisdiction
by way of business structures that prevent the charac-
terization of a permanent establishment (PE) within the
United Kingdom, either by the use artificial transactions
or of entities without economic substance.
This article deals specifically with the DPT levied when
a foreign company carries on activities in the United
Kingdom by means of a structure that is designed to avoid
the creation of a PE, i.e. a taxable presence, in the United
Kingdom. In such circumstances, the DPT targets situ-
ations where a non-resident company provides goods, ser-
vices or other properties in the United Kingdom through
a business model that avoids the characterization of a PE.1
The DPT is levied at a rate of 25%, which is higher than the
current standard corporation tax rate of 20% levied in the
United Kingdom. The tax base corresponds to the profits
that would have been attributed to the PE if its presence
had not been prevented by the taxpayer. The profits to be
subject to the DPT are calculated using the same domestic
taxrulesthatgoverntheallocationofprofitstoPEslocated
in the United Kingdom.
TheDPTmaybeconsideredthegreatestproofofinconsist-
ency in the attitude of certain European countries regard-
ing the debate on the allocation of taxing rights between
the source state and the residence state. In the recent past,
the main argument used by developed countries against
the taxation at source of technical services and adminis-
trative assistance was the absence of a PE in the source
*	 MasterofLaws(LL.M.)ininternationaltaxation,ViennaWirtschafts-
universität Wien (University of Economics and Business, WU) and
Master of Laws candidate in tax law, University of São Paulo (USP),
Member of the Scientific Committee, postgraduate course in interna-
tionaltaxlawoftheBrazilianInstituteofTaxLaw(IBDT)andVisiting
Professor,postgraduatecoursesinBrazil,andTaxAssociate,Marizde
Oliveira e Siqueira Campos Advogados. The author can be contacted
at rts@marizsiqueira.com.br
1.	 UK: Finance Act 2015, sec. 86.
state, thereby being able to demonstrate the existence of
an effective connection with its jurisdiction. However, as
soon as some US MNEs started to sell their products in the
UK consumer market without paying a supposedly “fair
share of tax”, the United Kingdom quickly introduced the
DPT into its national tax system to ensure the taxation of a
portion of the profit derived by such MNEs in its territory.
Despiteallreasonablejustificationsfortheadoptionofthis
unilateral tax measure, which departs from the proposals
presented by the OECD Base Erosion and Profit Shifting
(BEPS) initiative,2
the compatibility of the DPT with tax
treaties is very questionable.
2. The DPT and the Material Scope of Tax
Treaties
As reported, the UK government decided to implement
a new tax levied on diverted profits with the deliberate
intentionofexcludingthetaxfromthematerialscopeofits
tax treaties. However, regardless of the unilateral position
adopted by the UK government, the DPT should be exam-
ined carefully to verify whether it falls within tax treaties
based on the OECD Model.3
In this context, it should be noted that article 2 of the
OECD Model, which deals with the taxes covered by a
tax treaty, reads as follows:
	 1.	This convention shall apply to taxes on income
and on capital imposed on behalf of a Contract-
ing State or of its political subdivisions or local
authorities, irrespective of the manner in which
they are levied.
	 2.	There shall be regarded as taxes on income and
on capital all taxes imposed on total income, on
totalcapital,oronelementsofincomeorofcapital,
including taxed on gains from the alienation of
movableorimmovableproperty,taxedonthetotal
amounts of wages or salaries paid by enterprises,
as well as taxes on capital appreciation.
	(...)
	 4.	TheConventionshallapplyalsotoanyidenticalor
substantially similar taxes that are imposed after
the date of signature of the Convention in addi-
tion to, or in place of, the existing taxes. The com-
petent authorities of the Contracting States shall
2.	 See, for example, OECD, Addressing Base Erosion and Profit Shifting
(OECD 2013), International Organizations’ Documentation IBFD and
OECD, Action Plan on Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (OECD 2013), In-
ternational Organizations’ Documentation IBFD.
3.	 Most recently, OECD Model Tax Convention on Income and on Capital (26
July 2014), Models IBFD.
Ramon Tomazela Santos*International/United Kingdom
Exported / Printed on 20 July 2016 by biblio2@ibdt.org.br.
400 BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION JULY 2016 © IBFD
Ramon Tomazela Santos
notify each other of any significant changes that
have been made in their taxation laws.
As can be seen, article 2 of the OECD Model covers any
taxes levied on total income or on specific types of income
earned by taxpayers, regardless of the political subdivision
in state and the method of collection, for example, income
tax withheld at source or income tax levied on the basis
of a tax return.
In addition, identical or substantially similar taxes
imposed after the date of the signature of the tax treaty are
also covered in article 2(4) of the OECD Model. Indeed,
this provision contains an extension clause, which encom-
passes taxes introduced after the conclusion of a tax treaty
if they are identical or substantially similar to the taxes
originally covered. Such an extension clause preserves
the application of a tax treaty over the time, as it avoids
the fact that amendments to domestic laws make a tax
treaty inoperative. It also relieves the contracting states
from the obligation of renegotiating a tax treaty on each
modification of their domestic laws. Consequently, if the
new taxes imposed are identical or substantially similar
to those covered by the tax treaty, the levying of such tax
should comply with the treaty provisions agreed by the
contracting states.4
In general, the term “tax” means any charge levied by an
authority of a sovereign state on a person or property
underitsjurisdictiontoobtainfinancialresourcestocover
general public expenditure.5
As a result, the term “tax” has
a broad and generic meaning that encompasses almost all
amounts levied by a state based on its sovereignty, with a
few exceptions, such as the charges relating to administra-
tive policing powers, which are often referred to as “fees”.
All others forms of taxation, such as duties, excises and
socialcontributions,maybeincludedinthebroadconcept
of “tax”. Specifically with regard to the income tax, article
2(2) of the OECD Model adopts a very broad wording,
which covers not only a comprehensive income tax levied
on the total income earned by a taxpayer, but also specific
taxes that are levied on particular types of income.6
Appar-
ently, this broad definition could apply to the DPT levied
ontheprofitsdivertedfromtheUnitedKingdom’ smarket.
In contrast, it could be argued that the DPT is not sub-
stantially similar to income tax, as it has a specific scope
that encompasses a narrow number of taxpayers, as well
as a different tax rate. However, article 2(2) of the OECD
Model also covers tax levied on elements of income, such
as in a schedular income tax system, in which separate
taxes are imposed on different categories of income. In
addition, the applicable tax rate is not a decisive element
in defining whether a new tax is covered by article 2 of the
OECD Model, as it only quantifies the amount to be paid
to the government treasury, without determining the legal
nature of the tax due.
4.	 M.Lang,Introduction to the Law of Double Taxation Conventions,2ndedn.,
sec. 8. (IBFD/Linde 2013), Online Books IBFD.
5.	 A. Sampaio de Moraes Godoy, Direito Tributário International Contextu-
alizado pp. 28-119 (Quartier Latin 2009).
6.	 J. Hortalá i Vallvé, Comentarios a la Red Española de Convenios de Doble
Imposición pp. 65-66 (Thomson/Aranzadi 2007).
Further, the definition of PE is directly connected with
article 7 of tax treaties, which is the allocation rule applied
to business profits. As a consequence, if a country creates
a new type of tax that is levied on PEs, or on MNEs that
avoided the creation of a PE, on diverted profits, such a tax
would clearly fall within the material scope of tax treaties.
In the case under consideration, even the name of the new
tax indicates that it is levied on profits.
Strictly, the DPT is substantially similar to an income tax,
as its tax base corresponds exactly to the profits that would
havebeenattributedtoaPEhadataxpayerhadnotavoided
such a characterization in the United Kingdom. The tax
base is usually considered to be the most important factor
in identifying the similarities between new taxes and taxes
covered by article 2 of tax treaties. As a result, given the
similarities in the computation rules, it would appear that
the differences between the DPT and the regular income
tax levied on a PE in the United Kingdom are not so great
as to prevent the DPT from being regarded as a tax sub-
stantially similar to the income tax. It follows that, despite
themanoeuvreusedbytheUnitedKingdomtoimplement
a new tax, the DPT is covered by the material scope of its
tax treaties.
3. The DPT and the Equivalent of Article 7 of the
OECD Model in Tax Treaties
Assuming that the DPT is a substantially similar tax, the
question to be answered concerns its compatibility with
article 7 of tax treaties based on the OECD Model, given
that the United Kingdom intends to tax profits earned by
a non-resident company, regardless of the effective char-
acterization of a PE in its jurisdiction. In other words, the
question that arises is whether, in the event that the non-
resident company is headquartered in a state that has con-
cluded a tax treaty with the United Kingdom, the UK gov-
ernment may levy the DPT on profits allegedly diverted,
even without the effective characterization of a PE within
the state.
Article 7(1) of the OECD Model, as adopted by the United
Kingdom in most of its tax treaties, reads as follows:
Profits of an enterprise of a Contracting States shall be taxable
only in that State unless the enterprise carries on business in the
other Contracting State through a permanent establishment sit-
uated therein. If the enterprise carries on business as aforesaid,
the profits that are attributable to the permanent establishment
in accordance with the provisions of paragraph 2 may be taxed
in that other State.
Article 7(1) of tax treaties has the objective scope of pro-
tecting the profits earned by individuals or legal entities
resident in the other contracting state through the devel-
opment of an economic activity.7
Consequently, profits
arising from the exercise of a business activity should be
taxed exclusively in the residence state. The only excep-
tions to this general rule rely on the economic activity per-
7.	 L.E. Schoueri, The Objective Scope of Article 7 and the Treaty Protection
to Deemed Distributed Dividends Kluwer Intl. Tax Blog (2015), available
at http://www.kluwertaxlawblog.com/blog/2015/04/27/the-objective-
	scope-of-article-7-and-the-treaty-protection-to-deemed-distributed-
	dividends/.
Exported / Printed on 20 July 2016 by biblio2@ibdt.org.br.
401© IBFD BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION JULY 2016
The United Kingdom’ s Diverted Profits Tax and Tax Treaties: An Evaluation
formed in the source state being undertaken by way of a
PE, as well as on the income being classified under specific
distributive rules, which establish a specific allocation of
the right to tax.
It is, therefore, clear that article 7 of the OECD Model has a
universal scope, thereby serving as an umbrella for differ-
ent types of income derived from business activities. The
reason for this is because it covers the results arising from
the exercise of an economic activity conducted by a resi-
dent of a contracting state (i.e. the residence state) in the
other contracting state (i.e. the source state), provided that
therelevantincomeisnotexpresslydealtwithinoneofthe
specific distributive rules. That is why article 7(1) of the
OECD Model may be considered to be the heart of a tax
treaty, under which the largest portion of income derived
from international economic activities is classified.8
ThedefinitionofPEsetoutinarticle5oftheOECDModel
is one of the key concepts in tax treaties for the alloca-
tion of taxing rights relating to foreign business activities.
This is because the concept of a PE serves as a criterion to
legitimate the attribution of the taxing rights to the source
state. It also indicates a substantial degree of presence in
the economic life of the source state, which justifies the
taxation of a foreign person on the profits attributable to
the business activity developed in its consumer market, in
the same way as a domestic person.
Nevertheless, as the wording of the definition of a PE has
remained nearly unchanged for the last 50 years,9
new
business models developed during the last decades allow
taxpayers to derive a high level of income without a physi-
cal presence in the host state. MNEs can, therefore, have a
significant business presence in the economy of another
state, without becoming liable to tax due to the lack of
nexus under the current definition of a PE.
The DPT is intended to counter the artificial avoidance of
the status of a PE. However, the DPT does not appear to
differentiatebetweensituationsinwhichataxpayersimply
does not have a fixed place of business in the source state
over a particular duration of time from those in which a
taxpayer effectively makes use of schemes or pre-planned
arrangements that are designed to artificially avoid the
characterization of a PE in the source state.
Article 5 of the OECD Model deals with the following
three different types of PEs: (1) a general PE; (2) a con-
struction PE; and (3) a dependent agent PE. Each of these
definitions of a PE requires the presence of certain ele-
ments for its characterization, such as, inter alia: (1) a ter-
ritorial link evidenced by a fixed place of business; (2) a
time threshold that indicates the level of permanence; and
(3) the authority to conclude contracts in the name of the
enterprise. All of these concepts and requirements may be
usedbythetaxpayertodesignabusinessmodelthatavoids
the characterization of a PE in the source state, thereby
8.	 A. Xavier, Direito tributário internacional do Brasil p. 567 (Forense 2010).
9.	 A. Storck  A. Zeiler, Beyond the OECD Update 2014: Changes to the Con-
cepts of Permanent Establishment in the Light of the BEPS Discussion, in The
OECD-Model-Convention and its Update 2014 sec. I, p. 242 (M. Lang et al.
eds., IBFD/Linde 2015), Online Books IBFD.
reducing its tax burden. As a result, the current rules leave
room for the use of valid tax planning strategies in rela-
tion to the definition of a PE, as new economic activities
and technological developments offer a reasonable degree
of flexibility for the taxpayers to structure their business
without crossing the PE threshold.
Article 5(4) of the OECD Model also contains a list of
preparatory or auxiliary activities that are to be treated
as exceptions to the general definition of a PE, even when
a fixed place of business is characterized. Although orig-
inally designed for a different economic context, these
exemptions are granted by the treaty provision itself. As a
result, the simple adoption of a business model that either
avoids the characterization of a PE or exploits the exemp-
tions for preparatory or auxiliary activities cannot be con-
sidered to be the artificial avoidance of the status of a PE.
In practice, it is unclear whether the DPT only encom-
passes cases where a taxpayer artificially avoids the char-
acterization of a PE in the market jurisdiction through the
artificial fragmentation of its transaction. As the relevant
UK law is drafted in broad terms, it is very likely that the
DPT also affects cases in which the taxpayer designs its
businessmodeltofallwithinthePEthreshold,butwithout
using transactions structured in an artificial manner. In
this respect, only artificial structures, instigated exclu-
sively for tax purposes and with no economic substance,
should be countered by tax authorities.
If the structure adopted by a taxpayer is congruent with
the business model chosen, the tax authorities cannot dis-
regard a valid tax planning strategy just because it reduces
the tax liability in the source state. Conversely, when the
structure used by the taxpayer does not have a certain
degree of economic substance and coherence, the tax
authorities may counter it, irrespective of the introduc-
tion of a specific tax for that purpose.
The problem is that the United Kingdom intends to levy
the DPT on international structures adopted by MNEs
that were not intended to be covered by the PE definition
as originally drafted. Nevertheless, as these structures are
not artificial from a legal standpoint, the United Kingdom
should, in theory, renegotiate its tax treaties to amend the
definition of a PE, instead of levying a new tax.
As taxpayers have the right to choose the legal actions and
transactions that best fit their needs, the simple fact that
the business model adopted falls within the definition of a
PE does not, in itself, authorize the collection of a substan-
tially similar tax that contradicts the international obliga-
tions assumed in a tax treaty. This is why the levying of the
DPT should be restricted to cases where the tax authorities
can demonstrate the artificiality of the legal structure used
by the taxpayer or, at best, the lack of any other plausible
justification for the means adopted.
Recently, the OECD BEPS initiative has resurrected the
debate regarding the adequacy and convenience of the
concept of a PE with regard to the allocation of the tax
jurisdiction given the very significant pressure exerted by
developed countries. In particular, numerous European
countries, which have become a major market for many
Exported / Printed on 20 July 2016 by biblio2@ibdt.org.br.
402 BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION JULY 2016 © IBFD
Ramon Tomazela Santos
US MNEs, such as Amazon, Apple, Google and Starbucks,
have begun to demand more forcefully their right to tax
at least part of the profits derived by such MNEs in their
territories.
However, the proposals presented in Action 7 of the
OECD BEPS initiative reveal an unsuccessful attempt
to adapt an outdated concept to a new economic reality,
without directly challenging the paradigms of interna-
tional taxation.10
Action 7 only targets circumvention of
the PE definition, i.e. artificial fragmentation, commis-
sionaire arrangements, preparatory or auxiliary exemp-
tions, among others, without departing from the current
rules on the allocation of taxing rights between contract-
ing states. Consequently, as in the vast majority of Action
Plans in its BEPS initiative, the OECD has insisted on
maintaining the current paradigms of international taxa-
tion, in seeking only to adapt outdated concepts to a new
economic scenario.
The amendment of the PE definition, as envisaged under
Action 7 of the OECD BEPS initiative, would most prob-
ably not encompass all cases in which foreign enterprises
can undertake a substantial level of economic activity in
thesourcestatewithoutestablishingthedegreeofpresence
required by the PE threshold. Against this background, it
is easy to see why the United Kingdom decided to enact
the DPT to ensure the taxation of a portion of the profit
derived by such MNEs. The United Kingdom probably
found the approach followed by the OECD in Action 7
ineffective and, therefore, opted for the introduction of a
more radical tax measure that targets profits diverted to
other countries.
The point is that, despite all possible justifications, the
compatibility of the DPT with article 7 of the tax treaties
concluded by the United Kingdom is very questionable.
The various specific objections to the DPT with regard to
tax treaties are now summarized below.
First, the rules regarding the DPT do not only apply to
cases where the sole or main purpose of the taxpayer is to
avoid taxes. This would be essential in characterizing the
rule in the DPT as an anti-abuse provision. The use of UK
law is a simple mechanism that permits the taxation of any
sales or services undertaken in the UK internal market,
regardless of the characterization of a PE. This flagrantly
contradicts article 7 of the tax treaties.
Second, the deemed characterization of a PE based on
a domestic anti-abuse rule without the support of the
wording in a tax treaty could result in double taxation,
as a residence state only grants an exemption or a foreign
tax credit in relation to taxes levied in accordance with the
distributive rules of a tax treaty. Consequently, the imposi-
tion of the DPT by the United Kingdom could result in the
double taxation of corporate profits, which is precisely the
phenomenon that a tax treaty is intended to avoid.
10.	OECD, Action 7 Final Report 2015 – Preventing the Artificial Avoidance of
Permanent Establishment Status (OECD 2015), International Organiza-
tions’ Documentation IBFD.
This demonstrates that the United Kingdom should have
extended or amended the definition of a PE in its tax trea-
tiestoencompassnewactivitiesdevelopedwithoutaphys-
ical presence within the country. The United Kingdom
could also have included in its tax treaties specific anti-
avoidance rules against common tax planning strategies
used to avoid the characterization of a PE. What cannot
be agreed to is the introduction of a new tax to cover these
situations which violate treaty obligations.
The conclusion would be different if the DPT were to be
levied only when the taxpayer’ s conduct consisted of con-
cealing the existence of a PE in the source state by means of
fraudulent manoeuvres. However, as the UK law is drafted
in broad terms, it would appear that, in several cases where
a structure used by a taxpayer could not be considered to
be artificial, the levying of the DPT by the UK tax authori-
ties, Her Majesty’ s Revenue  Customs (HMRC), would
be incompatible with tax treaties.
4. Domestic Anti-Avoidance Rules and Tax
Treaties
Despite the protection granted by article 7 of the OECD
Model, HMRC could argue that the DPT would only be
levied in abusive situations involving the requalification
of legal structures used by taxpayers as artificially circum-
venting the concept of PE. Based on this, HMRC could
argue that, with the support of the OECD’ s position on
the compatibility of domestic general anti-avoidance rules
(GAARs) with treaty provisions, the mere requalification
of the facts, to be able to consider that there is a PE in the
United Kingdom, would not be affected by tax treaties.
This line of reasoning would allow the collection of the
DPT even in the face of a tax treaty.
In fact, the OECD argues, in the Commentary on Article
1 of the OECD Model, that:
... to the extent these anti-avoidance rules are part of the basic
domestic rules set by domestic tax laws for determining which
facts give rise to a tax liability, they are not addressed in tax trea-
ties and therefore not affected by them. Thus, as a general rule,
there will be no conflict between such rules and the provisions
of tax conventions.11
ThisinterpretationofthecompatibilityofdomesticGAARs
with the tax treaties, which is reinforced in the Commen-
tary on Article 1 of the OECD Model,12
is adopted by most
OECD member countries. The only exceptions are Lux-
embourg, the Netherlands and Switzerland, which have
recorded observations against such a questionable inter-
pretation as proposed by the OECD.13
This is not the place to review this subject in all of its vari-
eties. It is, however, important to present brief comments
regarding the position of the OECD on the compatibility
of domestic GAARs with treaty provisions.
Initially, it should be emphasized that the title of and the
preamble to tax treaties includes the purpose of avoiding
11.	 OECD Model Tax Convention on Income and on Capital: Commentary on
Article 1, para. 9.2 (26 July 2014), Models IBFD.
12.	 Id., at paras. 22.1 and 23.
13.	 Id., at paras. 27.6, 27.7 and 27.9.
Exported / Printed on 20 July 2016 by biblio2@ibdt.org.br.
403© IBFD BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION JULY 2016
The United Kingdom’ s Diverted Profits Tax and Tax Treaties: An Evaluation
double taxation and the prevention of tax evasion. As a
result, even if a prescriptive content is assigned to the pre-
amble of tax treaties, it is clear that domestic anti-abuse
rules may only be applied in conflict with the provisions of
tax treaties in the event of demonstrable tax evasion,14
but
not in the case of tax avoidance or tax mitigation.
The passages of the Commentaries on the OECD Model
that use the term “tax avoidance” are mainly related to the
exchange of information and administrative assistance
in the collection of taxes. Consequently, it is not possible
to include the efforts aimed at tax avoidance as a general
objective of tax treaties, which should guide the interpre-
tation of their provisions, in the light of article 31(1) of the
Vienna Convention on the Law of Treaties (the Vienna
Convention) (1969).15
In addition, in other passages that refer to the need to
counter tax avoidance, it has been expressly decided to
include specific anti-avoidance measures in the OECD
Model, such as: (1) the concept of beneficial owner in art-
icles 10 (Dividends), 11 (Interest) and 12 (Royalties); (2)
the replacement of the expression “each fiscal year” with
“any twelve month period” in article 15 (Income from
employment); and (3) the inclusion of article 17(2) (Enter-
tainers and Sportspersons), which permits the taxation at
source of income attributed to star companies, regardless
of the use of an artificial structure by the entertainer or
sportsperson.
These examples demonstrate that, in order to deal with
tax avoidance, states should amend the wording of treaty
provisions to prevent their circumvention by taxpayers
by way of tax planning, rather than simply implement
domestic anti-avoidance rules that overlap with the obli-
gations assumed at an international level, which consti-
tutes a treaty override.16
The application of domestic anti-avoidance rules may also
result in an unilateral change of a tax treatment granted by
a tax treaty, as the tax obligation created by the domestic
law of a contracting state, based on its interaction with the
domesticanti-avoidancerules,maymodifyorfrustratethe
effects that could have been derived from the application
of the tax treaty.17
This is precisely what may happen in
the case under analysis, as the DPT as levied by the United
Kingdom frustrates the typical effects derived from article
7 of the OECD Model, which provides for the exclusive
taxation of business profits in the residence state, except
where a PE can be characterized in the source state, which
does not occur in the case of the DPT.
In addition, the position expressed by the OECD in para-
graph 9.2 of the Commentary on Article 1 of the OECD
14.	 G. Maisto, Domestic Anti-Abuse Rules and Bilateral Tax Conventions in
the Light of Public International Law, in Essays on Tax Treaties A Tribute
to David A. Ward pp. 334/335 (G. Maisto, A. Nikolakakis  J.M. Ulmer
eds., IBFD/CTF 2012).
15.	 UNViennaConventionontheLawofTreaties(23May1969),TreatiesIBFD.
16.	 With regard to treaty override, see L.E. Schoueri, Tax Treaty Override A
Jurisdictional Approach, 42 Intertax 11 (2014) and C. de Pietro, Tax Treaty
Override (Kluwer L. Intl. 2014).
17.	Maisto, supra n. 14, at p. 336.
Model was only first included in 2003.18
This makes its
application questionable with regard to tax treaties con-
cluded before 2003.
It is known that the OECD argues that the amendments
to the Commentaries on the OECD Model are not rele-
vant for the interpretation and application of tax treaties
concluded prior to their issue when there is a difference
in substance.19
On the other hand, where the amendments
to the OECD Commentaries are regarded as merely inter-
pretive, the OECD argues that such clarifications should
be applied to existing tax treaties20,21
to the extent that
they reflect the consensus of the OECD member coun-
tries regarding the correct interpretation of existing treaty
provisions and their proper application to actual cases.22,23
It can sometimes be difficult to identify whether a change
to the Commentaries on the OECD Model has instituted
a substantial change in the underlying treaty provision,
especially when the wording of the OECD Model itself
remains unchanged.24
Despite this, when it comes to the
compatibility of domestic anti-abuse rules with tax trea-
ties, the new position adopted by the OECD is diamet-
rically opposed to that which had been adopted by the
OECD since the Commentaries on the OECD Model
(1977),25
which makes the change made in the Commen-
taries on the OECD Model 2003 applicable only to tax
treaties entered into after that date.26
In fact, the pre-2003
version of the Commentaries on the OECD Model sug-
gested that:
it may be appropriate for Contracting States to agree in bilateral
negotiations that any relief from tax [provided by a tax treaty]
should not apply in certain cases, or to agree that the application
of the provisions of domestic laws against tax avoidance should
not be affected by the Convention.27
Thus, the pre-2003 version followed the view that domes-
tic anti-avoidance rules should be either included or
18.	 OECD Model Tax Convention on Income and on Capital: Commentary on
Article 1 para. 9.2. (28 Jan. 2003), Models IBFD.
19.	 M. Schmitt, The Relevance of Amendments to the OECD Commentary for
the Interpretation of Tax Treaties (Static or Dynamic Approach), in Funda-
mental Issues and Practical Problems in Tax Treaty Interpretation p. 121 (M.
Schilcher  P. Weninger eds., Linde 2008).
20.	 M. Lang, The Application of the OECD Model Tax Convention to Partner-
ships A Critical Analysis of the Report Prepared by the OECD Committee
on Fiscal Affairs p. 15 (Linde 2000).
21.	 K. Provodová, The Relevance of the OECD Report for the Interpretation of
Tax Treaties, in Schilcher  Weninger, supra n. 19, at p. 151.
22.	 Seepara.35oftheintroductiontotheOECD Model: Commentaries(2014),
according to which: “Needless to say, amendments to the Articles of the
Model Convention and to the Commentaries that are a direct result of
these amendments are not relevant to the interpretation or application
of previously concluded conventions where the provisions of those con-
ventions are different in substance from the amended Articles. However,
other changes or additions to the Commentaries are normally applicable
to the interpretation and application of conventions concluded before
their adoption, because they reflect the consensus of the OECD Member
countries as to the proper interpretation of existing provisions and their
application to specific situations.”
23.	Schmitt, supra n. 19, at p. 121.
24.	 G. Nolte, Report 3. Subsequent Agreements and Subsequent Practice of States
Outside of Judicial or Quasi-judicial Proceedings, in Treaties and Subsequent
Practice p. 362 (G. Nolte ed., Oxford U. Press 2013).
25.	 OECD Model Tax Convention on Income and on Capital: Commentary on
Article 1 para. 10 (11 Apr. 1977), Models IBFD.
26.	Maisto, supra n. 14, at p. 339.
27.	OECD, supra n. 25, at para. 10.
Exported / Printed on 20 July 2016 by biblio2@ibdt.org.br.
404 BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION JULY 2016 © IBFD
Ramon Tomazela Santos
confirmed by tax treaty provisions. This approach only
changed in 2003, when the OECD put forward the argu-
ment that domestic anti-avoidance rules are used to deter-
mine the facts that create the tax obligation. Therefore,
since these changes in the Commentaries represent a new
interpretation, there are good grounds to claim that they
cannot be applied to older tax treaties. In any event, due to
the lack of consensus on the legal status of the Commen-
taryanditsroleintheinterpretationoftaxtreaties,ithasto
be acknowledged that tax authorities and national courts
may adopt different positions in this regard.
A more critical point relies on the fact that the United
KingdomsharestheviewoftheOECD,setoutintheCom-
mentary on Article 1 of the OECD Model,28
in the sense
that tax treaties do not affect the application of domestic
anti-abuse rules, as the United Kingdom representatives
did not record any observation against this interpretation.
As a result, regardless of the legal relevance to be attributed
to the Commentaries on the OECD Mode,29
it is clear that
the United Kingdom, in interpreting its tax treaties, acts in
good faith and in accordance with its unilateral stance, as
it did not make any observation on the content of relevant
paragraphs of the OECD Commentaries.30
The matter becomes even more complex when it is con-
sidered that the UK tax law provides that its GAAR can
be applied in a treaty context31
to counter any tax arrange-
mentswhenitisreasonabletoconclude,havingtakenallof
the facts and circumstances into account, that a taxpayer
intended to obtain a tax advantage. In this sense, HMRC
has clearly stated that:
where there are abusive arrangements which try to exploit par-
ticular provisions in a double tax treaty, or the way in which such
provisions interact with other provisions of UK tax law, then the
GAAR can be applied to counteract the abusive arrangement.32
Although the UK tax law extends its GAAR to a treaty
context, this domestic legal provision may also give rise to
a debate about whether it constitutes a treaty override,33
as
it is a later domestic law that can be applied by HMRC in
conflict with treaty provisions. A treaty override, in addi-
tion to representing a breach of international law, also
gives rise to serious consequences, as it undermines the
legal certainty that tax treaties intend to develop. From
an international law perspective, article 60 of the Vienna
Convention (1969) establishes that:
28.	 Para. 9.2 OECD Model: Commentary on Article 1 (2014).
29.	 It is not within the scope of this article to analyse the legal relevance of
the OECD Model: Commentaries (2014). In this context, see J.M. Mössner,
Klaus Vogel Lecture 2009 Comments, 64 Bull. Intl. Taxn. 1, sec. 2. (2010),
Journals IBFD. It is assumed here that the relevance to be attributed to
the OECD Model: Commentaries (2014) should be considered on a case-
by-case basis. With regard to this, see J. Sasseville, Temporal Aspects of Tax
Treaties, in Tax Polymath: A Life in International Taxation Essays in Honour
of John F. Avery Jones sec. 3, p. 46 (P. Baker  C. Bobbett eds., IBFD 2011),
Online Books IBFD.
30.	 Paras. 9.2, 22.1 and 23 OECD Model: Commentary on Article 1 (2014).
31.	 J. Schwarz, Schwarz on Tax Treaties, 3rd edn., p. 45 (Wolters Kluwer (UK)
Ltd. 2013).
32.	HMRC, General Anti Abuse Rule (GAAR) Guidance, para. B.53, available
at www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/
	file/399270/2__HMRC_GAAR_Guidance_Parts_A-C_with_effect_
from_30_January_2015_AD_V6.pdf.
33.	Schwarz, supra n. 31.
a material breach of a bilateral treaty by one of the parties entitles
the other to invoke the breach as a ground for terminating the
treaty or suspending its operation in whole or in part.
From economic and practical perspectives, non-resident
taxpayers may lose their confidence in the behaviour of
the other contracting state, as the tax treatment applying
to their investments may suddenly be amended by a uni-
lateral and uncoordinated action.
Additionally, as tax treaties are primarily concluded by
sovereign states, it is clear that the provisions set out in
tax treaties must be observed in view of the international
public law principle of pacta sunt servanda, as set out in
article 26 of the Vienna Convention (1969), which pro-
vides that “every treaty in force is binding upon the parties
and must be performed in good faith”. This fundamen-
tal principle is supplemented by article 27 of the Vienna
Convention (1969), according to which “a party may not
invoke the provisions of internal law as a justification for
its failure to perform a treaty”. Consequently, the contract-
ing states embrace a commitment that binds them to not
impose taxes on situations in which a tax treaty restricts
their taxing rights. Under the international law, there are
no possible justifications for a treaty override.34
As a result,
even if, under the UK legal system, the doctrine of parlia-
mentary sovereignty admits the enactment of domestic
laws to override a treaty provision, such a breach of in-
ternational law may be invoked by the other contracting
state.35
In addition to this infringement, which may be questioned
bytheothercontractingstate,itshouldbeemphasizedthat
the domestic GAAR enacted by the United Kingdom and
extended to the level of tax treaties does not represent a
general legitimization of the DPT. The domestic GAAR
may be used by HMRC to counter tax advantages arising
from tax arrangements that are abusive, but it does not
legitimatetheimpositionoftheDPTinanycircumstances,
without demonstrating a practice of abusive tax arrange-
ments by a taxpayer.
It is also important to note that the fictitious character-
ization of a PE on the basis of a domestic anti-abuse rule
without the support of the wording in the tax treaty may
result in double taxation, as the residence state only grants
a credit or an exemption in relation to the taxes levied in
accordance with the distributive rules of a tax treaty.36
Even if the United Kingdom were to apply its domestic
GAAR on the basis that a taxpayer intentionally avoided
the characterization of a PE, the other contracting state
could hardly adopt the same approach in granting double
taxationreliefinatreatycontext.Consequently,thecollec-
tion of DPT by the United Kingdom could easily result in
the double taxation of business profits, which is precisely
what a tax treaty is designed to prevent.
34.	 P. Ribeiro de Souza, Tax Treaty Override, in Schilcher  Weninger, supra
n. 19, at p. 255.
35.	Schwarz, supra n. 31, at p. 42.
36.	 M. Helminen, The International Tax Law Concept of Dividend, Series on
International Taxation vol. 36, pp. 105-106 (Kluwer L. Intl. 2010).
Exported / Printed on 20 July 2016 by biblio2@ibdt.org.br.
405© IBFD BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION JULY 2016
The United Kingdom’ s Diverted Profits Tax and Tax Treaties: An Evaluation
As a result, even if the position of the United Kingdom
and its domestic GAAR is considered to consistent with
the interpretation in the Commentaries on the OECDC
Model, the truth is that the collection of the DPT would be
contrary to the objective and purpose of a tax treaty. Con-
sequently, in a treaty context, the levying of the DPT could
only be justified in cases of proven abusive transactions.
Another aspect that must be addressed is the fact that
various tax treaties concluded by the United Kingdom
contain a general anti-abuse clause based on the principal
purpose test (PPT). The PPT permits the investigation of
the business purpose that guided a taxpayer in undertak-
ingcertainactionsortransactions.Theapplicationofsuch
a clause to justify the collection of the DPT would depend
on a case-by-case analysis. With regard to tax treaties with
PPT clauses, tax authorities can only reclassify an action
or a transaction carried out by a taxpayer when one of the
main purposes of the action or transaction is to prevent,
reduce or delay the payment of taxes, without any other
economic or business purpose. As a result, only actions or
transactions undertaken with the sole or main purpose of
avoiding taxes could be recharacterized by tax authorities.
Nevertheless, as stated in section 3., the DPT rules do not
appear to require an investigation as to whether the sole
or primary purpose of a taxpayer is to avoid taxes. In this
context, it can be asked whether the DPT is really intended
to counter cases in which MNEs artificially avoid the char-
acterization of a PE in the United Kingdom without any
other business purpose or, conversely, whether it is only
a stringent mechanism to tax any sales or services per-
formed in the UK domestic market, regardless of the char-
acterization of a PE. In the latter case, even if the relevant
tax treaty contains a PPT clause, it is possible to challenge
the compatibility of the DPT with the equivalent to article
7 of the OECD Model in the tax treaty, given that the tax
is levied on the profits obtained by a company resident in
the other contracting state without the characterization of
a PE in the United Kingdom.
Finally, it should be noted that, in the UK tax system, tax
treaties only have effect insofar as domestic law so pro-
vides. It may be debatable whether the Taxation (Inter-
national and Other Provisions) Act (TIOPA) 2010 gives
effect to tax treaties in relation to DPT, as this states that:
[d]ouble taxation arrangements have effect in relation to income
tax and corporation tax so far as the arrangements provide ... (b)
for taxing income of non-UK resident persons that arises from
sources in the United Kingdom.37
Although the DPT cannot be considered to be income tax
or corporation tax under the UK domestic tax law, it is
37.	 UK: Taxation (International and Other Provisions) Act (TIOPA) sec. 6(2)
(b) 2010.
undeniable that a tax treaty validly concluded is binding
from an international law perspective. For this reason, the
other contracting state may challenge the breach of the
provisions of a tax treaty by the United Kingdom given
the introduction of the DPT. This may result in a tax treaty
being terminated or suspended under international law.
5. Conclusions
The equivalent of article 2(4) of the OECD
Model in the tax treaties concluded by the United
Kingdom encompasses any identical or substantially
similar taxes that are imposed after the date of the
signature of a tax treaty. As the tax base of the DPT
corresponds to the profits that would have been
attributed to a PE, it can be considered to be a tax
levied on elements of income.
As taxpayers have the right to choose the actions
and transactions that they put into effect, the simple
fact that the business model adopted falls within the
definition of a PE does not authorize the collection
of a similar tax, in contradiction to the international
obligations assumed in a tax treaty. Consequently,
the levying of the DPT should be restricted to
cases where HMRC can clearly demonstrate the
artificiality of the legal structure used by a taxpayer.
In addition, if the structure used by the taxpayer
has an unintended result in light of the traditional
definition of a PE, the United Kingdom should
renegotiate its tax treaties to amend the definition of
a PE, instead of imposing a new tax.
Although UK tax law provides that its GAAR can
be applied in a treaty context, such a breach of
international law through a treaty override may be
invoked by the other contracting state to terminate
the tax treaty. In addition, the fact that the UK
domestic GAAR may be used by HMRC to counter
artificial tax arrangements does not legitimate the
levying of the DPT in any circumstances, without
proof of abuse.
Finally, despite the fact that, within the UK legal
system, tax treaties only have effect insofar as the
domestic law so provides, it is undeniable that a
tax treaty validly concluded is binding from an
international law perspective. Consequently, the
other contracting state may challenge the breach of
the tax treaty by the United Kingdom arising as a
result of the introduction of the DPT.
Exported / Printed on 20 July 2016 by biblio2@ibdt.org.br.

Mais conteúdo relacionado

Mais procurados

Carried interest - UK and US developments
Carried interest - UK and US developmentsCarried interest - UK and US developments
Carried interest - UK and US developmentsDarrin Henderson
 
BEPS filing requirements for multinationals under country by country reporting
BEPS filing requirements for multinationals under country by country reportingBEPS filing requirements for multinationals under country by country reporting
BEPS filing requirements for multinationals under country by country reportingPaul Authachinda
 
2016 Handbook: Doing business in Germany
2016 Handbook: Doing business in Germany2016 Handbook: Doing business in Germany
2016 Handbook: Doing business in GermanyAccace
 
Erich Baier Präsentation Ubo 2011
Erich Baier Präsentation Ubo 2011Erich Baier Präsentation Ubo 2011
Erich Baier Präsentation Ubo 2011Boitelle
 
2019, EU Izveštaj o napretku, Srbija
2019, EU Izveštaj o napretku, Srbija2019, EU Izveštaj o napretku, Srbija
2019, EU Izveštaj o napretku, Srbijagordana comic
 
Ekeocha revenue implications of nigeria's tax system
Ekeocha revenue implications of nigeria's tax systemEkeocha revenue implications of nigeria's tax system
Ekeocha revenue implications of nigeria's tax systemAlexander Decker
 
Pub. finance ppt copy
Pub. finance ppt   copyPub. finance ppt   copy
Pub. finance ppt copyDrneetu2
 
Australian Taxation System
Australian Taxation SystemAustralian Taxation System
Australian Taxation SystemEmie Rose Palmes
 
Newsletter LPA LEGAL Albania January 2020
Newsletter LPA LEGAL Albania January 2020Newsletter LPA LEGAL Albania January 2020
Newsletter LPA LEGAL Albania January 2020Oltjan Hoxholli
 
WIRC - Planning Investments through various jurisdictions - Cyprus presentati...
WIRC - Planning Investments through various jurisdictions - Cyprus presentati...WIRC - Planning Investments through various jurisdictions - Cyprus presentati...
WIRC - Planning Investments through various jurisdictions - Cyprus presentati...P P Shah & Associates
 
Tax Alert 164 February 2017
Tax Alert 164 February 2017Tax Alert 164 February 2017
Tax Alert 164 February 2017Loyens & Loeff
 
Grant Thornton Hungary Tax News - November 2014 en (2)
Grant Thornton Hungary Tax News - November 2014 en (2)Grant Thornton Hungary Tax News - November 2014 en (2)
Grant Thornton Hungary Tax News - November 2014 en (2)Alex Baulf
 
Vat revenue and state investment spending in nigeria, 1994 2010.
Vat revenue and state investment spending in nigeria, 1994 2010.Vat revenue and state investment spending in nigeria, 1994 2010.
Vat revenue and state investment spending in nigeria, 1994 2010.Alexander Decker
 
FY 2017-2018 State Tax Revenue
FY 2017-2018 State Tax RevenueFY 2017-2018 State Tax Revenue
FY 2017-2018 State Tax Revenuecutmytaxes
 
Towards a rational tax policy in the czech republic
Towards a rational tax policy in the czech republicTowards a rational tax policy in the czech republic
Towards a rational tax policy in the czech republicColin Shea
 

Mais procurados (20)

Carried interest - UK and US developments
Carried interest - UK and US developmentsCarried interest - UK and US developments
Carried interest - UK and US developments
 
BEPS filing requirements for multinationals under country by country reporting
BEPS filing requirements for multinationals under country by country reportingBEPS filing requirements for multinationals under country by country reporting
BEPS filing requirements for multinationals under country by country reporting
 
2016 Handbook: Doing business in Germany
2016 Handbook: Doing business in Germany2016 Handbook: Doing business in Germany
2016 Handbook: Doing business in Germany
 
Erich Baier Präsentation Ubo 2011
Erich Baier Präsentation Ubo 2011Erich Baier Präsentation Ubo 2011
Erich Baier Präsentation Ubo 2011
 
Report evat
Report evatReport evat
Report evat
 
2019, EU Izveštaj o napretku, Srbija
2019, EU Izveštaj o napretku, Srbija2019, EU Izveštaj o napretku, Srbija
2019, EU Izveštaj o napretku, Srbija
 
Ekeocha revenue implications of nigeria's tax system
Ekeocha revenue implications of nigeria's tax systemEkeocha revenue implications of nigeria's tax system
Ekeocha revenue implications of nigeria's tax system
 
excise tax
excise tax excise tax
excise tax
 
Pub. finance ppt copy
Pub. finance ppt   copyPub. finance ppt   copy
Pub. finance ppt copy
 
Australian Taxation System
Australian Taxation SystemAustralian Taxation System
Australian Taxation System
 
Newsletter LPA LEGAL Albania January 2020
Newsletter LPA LEGAL Albania January 2020Newsletter LPA LEGAL Albania January 2020
Newsletter LPA LEGAL Albania January 2020
 
debarment_in_europe
debarment_in_europedebarment_in_europe
debarment_in_europe
 
WIRC - Planning Investments through various jurisdictions - Cyprus presentati...
WIRC - Planning Investments through various jurisdictions - Cyprus presentati...WIRC - Planning Investments through various jurisdictions - Cyprus presentati...
WIRC - Planning Investments through various jurisdictions - Cyprus presentati...
 
Tax Alert 164 February 2017
Tax Alert 164 February 2017Tax Alert 164 February 2017
Tax Alert 164 February 2017
 
Grant Thornton Hungary Tax News - November 2014 en (2)
Grant Thornton Hungary Tax News - November 2014 en (2)Grant Thornton Hungary Tax News - November 2014 en (2)
Grant Thornton Hungary Tax News - November 2014 en (2)
 
Vat revenue and state investment spending in nigeria, 1994 2010.
Vat revenue and state investment spending in nigeria, 1994 2010.Vat revenue and state investment spending in nigeria, 1994 2010.
Vat revenue and state investment spending in nigeria, 1994 2010.
 
Trends in Federal Tax Revenues and Rates
Trends in Federal Tax Revenues and RatesTrends in Federal Tax Revenues and Rates
Trends in Federal Tax Revenues and Rates
 
accountancy_digital_EN
accountancy_digital_ENaccountancy_digital_EN
accountancy_digital_EN
 
FY 2017-2018 State Tax Revenue
FY 2017-2018 State Tax RevenueFY 2017-2018 State Tax Revenue
FY 2017-2018 State Tax Revenue
 
Towards a rational tax policy in the czech republic
Towards a rational tax policy in the czech republicTowards a rational tax policy in the czech republic
Towards a rational tax policy in the czech republic
 

Destaque

Instrumentos financeiros híbridos e arbitragem fiscal internacional
 Instrumentos financeiros híbridos e arbitragem fiscal internacional Instrumentos financeiros híbridos e arbitragem fiscal internacional
Instrumentos financeiros híbridos e arbitragem fiscal internacionalRamon Tomazela
 
Tutorial para usar o slideshare
Tutorial para usar o slideshareTutorial para usar o slideshare
Tutorial para usar o slideshareProjeto UCA
 
LinkedIn Quiz: Which Parent Are You When It Comes to Helping Guide Your Child...
LinkedIn Quiz: Which Parent Are You When It Comes to Helping Guide Your Child...LinkedIn Quiz: Which Parent Are You When It Comes to Helping Guide Your Child...
LinkedIn Quiz: Which Parent Are You When It Comes to Helping Guide Your Child...LinkedIn
 
So you want to be a wizard
So you want to be a wizardSo you want to be a wizard
So you want to be a wizardJulia Evans
 
Seo camp'us 2017 utiliser google analytics comme un voyou - aristide riou
Seo camp'us 2017   utiliser google analytics comme un voyou - aristide riouSeo camp'us 2017   utiliser google analytics comme un voyou - aristide riou
Seo camp'us 2017 utiliser google analytics comme un voyou - aristide riouPrénom Nom de famille
 
2015 Upload Campaigns Calendar - SlideShare
2015 Upload Campaigns Calendar - SlideShare2015 Upload Campaigns Calendar - SlideShare
2015 Upload Campaigns Calendar - SlideShareSlideShare
 
What to Upload to SlideShare
What to Upload to SlideShareWhat to Upload to SlideShare
What to Upload to SlideShareSlideShare
 
How to Make Awesome SlideShares: Tips & Tricks
How to Make Awesome SlideShares: Tips & TricksHow to Make Awesome SlideShares: Tips & Tricks
How to Make Awesome SlideShares: Tips & TricksSlideShare
 
Getting Started With SlideShare
Getting Started With SlideShareGetting Started With SlideShare
Getting Started With SlideShareSlideShare
 

Destaque (9)

Instrumentos financeiros híbridos e arbitragem fiscal internacional
 Instrumentos financeiros híbridos e arbitragem fiscal internacional Instrumentos financeiros híbridos e arbitragem fiscal internacional
Instrumentos financeiros híbridos e arbitragem fiscal internacional
 
Tutorial para usar o slideshare
Tutorial para usar o slideshareTutorial para usar o slideshare
Tutorial para usar o slideshare
 
LinkedIn Quiz: Which Parent Are You When It Comes to Helping Guide Your Child...
LinkedIn Quiz: Which Parent Are You When It Comes to Helping Guide Your Child...LinkedIn Quiz: Which Parent Are You When It Comes to Helping Guide Your Child...
LinkedIn Quiz: Which Parent Are You When It Comes to Helping Guide Your Child...
 
So you want to be a wizard
So you want to be a wizardSo you want to be a wizard
So you want to be a wizard
 
Seo camp'us 2017 utiliser google analytics comme un voyou - aristide riou
Seo camp'us 2017   utiliser google analytics comme un voyou - aristide riouSeo camp'us 2017   utiliser google analytics comme un voyou - aristide riou
Seo camp'us 2017 utiliser google analytics comme un voyou - aristide riou
 
2015 Upload Campaigns Calendar - SlideShare
2015 Upload Campaigns Calendar - SlideShare2015 Upload Campaigns Calendar - SlideShare
2015 Upload Campaigns Calendar - SlideShare
 
What to Upload to SlideShare
What to Upload to SlideShareWhat to Upload to SlideShare
What to Upload to SlideShare
 
How to Make Awesome SlideShares: Tips & Tricks
How to Make Awesome SlideShares: Tips & TricksHow to Make Awesome SlideShares: Tips & Tricks
How to Make Awesome SlideShares: Tips & Tricks
 
Getting Started With SlideShare
Getting Started With SlideShareGetting Started With SlideShare
Getting Started With SlideShare
 

Semelhante a The United Kingdom’ s Diverted Profits Tax and Tax Treaties: An Evaluation

A Critical Evaluation of the OECD's BEPS Project
A Critical Evaluation of the OECD's BEPS ProjectA Critical Evaluation of the OECD's BEPS Project
A Critical Evaluation of the OECD's BEPS ProjectRamon Tomazela
 
US desk quarterly newsletter - September 2016 edition
US desk quarterly newsletter - September 2016 editionUS desk quarterly newsletter - September 2016 edition
US desk quarterly newsletter - September 2016 editionQuentin Van Gansberghe
 
Us desk quarterly newsletter september 2016 edition
Us desk quarterly newsletter   september 2016 editionUs desk quarterly newsletter   september 2016 edition
Us desk quarterly newsletter september 2016 editionQuentin Van Gansberghe
 
US desk quarterly newsletter - December 2016 edition
US desk quarterly newsletter - December 2016 editionUS desk quarterly newsletter - December 2016 edition
US desk quarterly newsletter - December 2016 editionVesko Petkov
 
VIETNAM TAXATION – OUTLOOK ON THE EUROPEAN UNION VIETNAM FREE TRADE AGREEMENT...
VIETNAM TAXATION – OUTLOOK ON THE EUROPEAN UNION VIETNAM FREE TRADE AGREEMENT...VIETNAM TAXATION – OUTLOOK ON THE EUROPEAN UNION VIETNAM FREE TRADE AGREEMENT...
VIETNAM TAXATION – OUTLOOK ON THE EUROPEAN UNION VIETNAM FREE TRADE AGREEMENT...Dr. Oliver Massmann
 
VIETNAM TAX ISSUES – OUTLOOK ON THE EUROPEAN UNION VIETNAM FREE TRADE AGREEME...
VIETNAM TAX ISSUES – OUTLOOK ON THE EUROPEAN UNION VIETNAM FREE TRADE AGREEME...VIETNAM TAX ISSUES – OUTLOOK ON THE EUROPEAN UNION VIETNAM FREE TRADE AGREEME...
VIETNAM TAX ISSUES – OUTLOOK ON THE EUROPEAN UNION VIETNAM FREE TRADE AGREEME...Dr. Oliver Massmann
 
MEXICO’S 2014 TAX REFORM: A BRIEF REVIEW OF SOME OF ITS MOST RELEVANT ISSUES
MEXICO’S 2014 TAX REFORM: A BRIEF REVIEW OF SOME OF ITS MOST RELEVANT ISSUESMEXICO’S 2014 TAX REFORM: A BRIEF REVIEW OF SOME OF ITS MOST RELEVANT ISSUES
MEXICO’S 2014 TAX REFORM: A BRIEF REVIEW OF SOME OF ITS MOST RELEVANT ISSUESHogan Lovells BSTL
 
Permanent Establishment May Not Be So Permanent (Prepare for Change)
Permanent Establishment May Not Be So Permanent (Prepare for Change)Permanent Establishment May Not Be So Permanent (Prepare for Change)
Permanent Establishment May Not Be So Permanent (Prepare for Change)Accounting_Whitepapers
 
The csll and the substantive scope of brazilian tax treaties
The csll and the substantive scope of brazilian tax treatiesThe csll and the substantive scope of brazilian tax treaties
The csll and the substantive scope of brazilian tax treatiesRamon Tomazela
 
Global Indirect Tax Outlook - 2017 and Beyond
Global Indirect Tax Outlook - 2017 and BeyondGlobal Indirect Tax Outlook - 2017 and Beyond
Global Indirect Tax Outlook - 2017 and BeyondDavid Duffy
 
Diverted Profits Tax (a) Google Tax: United Kingdom’s combat against tax evasion
Diverted Profits Tax (a) Google Tax: United Kingdom’s combat against tax evasionDiverted Profits Tax (a) Google Tax: United Kingdom’s combat against tax evasion
Diverted Profits Tax (a) Google Tax: United Kingdom’s combat against tax evasionThangadurai Punithan
 
Base Erosion and Profit Shifting - An overview
Base Erosion and Profit Shifting - An overviewBase Erosion and Profit Shifting - An overview
Base Erosion and Profit Shifting - An overviewTAXPERT PROFESSIONALS
 
Base Erosion Profit Shifting_Overview
Base Erosion Profit Shifting_Overview Base Erosion Profit Shifting_Overview
Base Erosion Profit Shifting_Overview TAXPERT PROFESSIONALS
 
Corporate Sustainability Due Diligence Directive (CSDDD or the EU Supply Chai...
Corporate Sustainability Due Diligence Directive (CSDDD or the EU Supply Chai...Corporate Sustainability Due Diligence Directive (CSDDD or the EU Supply Chai...
Corporate Sustainability Due Diligence Directive (CSDDD or the EU Supply Chai...Dr. Oliver Massmann
 
Briefing Paper: Mini One-Stop-Shop
Briefing Paper: Mini One-Stop-ShopBriefing Paper: Mini One-Stop-Shop
Briefing Paper: Mini One-Stop-ShopGraham Brearley
 
VIETNAM – LATEST GUIDE TO CONTRACT MANUFACTURING AND TOLLING AGREEMENTS
VIETNAM – LATEST GUIDE TO CONTRACT MANUFACTURING AND TOLLING AGREEMENTSVIETNAM – LATEST GUIDE TO CONTRACT MANUFACTURING AND TOLLING AGREEMENTS
VIETNAM – LATEST GUIDE TO CONTRACT MANUFACTURING AND TOLLING AGREEMENTSDr. Oliver Massmann
 
International tax newsletter september 2017 - Kreston International
International tax newsletter   september 2017 - Kreston InternationalInternational tax newsletter   september 2017 - Kreston International
International tax newsletter september 2017 - Kreston InternationalKreston MCA
 

Semelhante a The United Kingdom’ s Diverted Profits Tax and Tax Treaties: An Evaluation (20)

pwc-international-tax-news-august-2015
pwc-international-tax-news-august-2015pwc-international-tax-news-august-2015
pwc-international-tax-news-august-2015
 
A Critical Evaluation of the OECD's BEPS Project
A Critical Evaluation of the OECD's BEPS ProjectA Critical Evaluation of the OECD's BEPS Project
A Critical Evaluation of the OECD's BEPS Project
 
US desk quarterly newsletter - September 2016 edition
US desk quarterly newsletter - September 2016 editionUS desk quarterly newsletter - September 2016 edition
US desk quarterly newsletter - September 2016 edition
 
Us desk quarterly newsletter september 2016 edition
Us desk quarterly newsletter   september 2016 editionUs desk quarterly newsletter   september 2016 edition
Us desk quarterly newsletter september 2016 edition
 
US desk quarterly newsletter - December 2016 edition
US desk quarterly newsletter - December 2016 editionUS desk quarterly newsletter - December 2016 edition
US desk quarterly newsletter - December 2016 edition
 
Ated
AtedAted
Ated
 
VIETNAM TAXATION – OUTLOOK ON THE EUROPEAN UNION VIETNAM FREE TRADE AGREEMENT...
VIETNAM TAXATION – OUTLOOK ON THE EUROPEAN UNION VIETNAM FREE TRADE AGREEMENT...VIETNAM TAXATION – OUTLOOK ON THE EUROPEAN UNION VIETNAM FREE TRADE AGREEMENT...
VIETNAM TAXATION – OUTLOOK ON THE EUROPEAN UNION VIETNAM FREE TRADE AGREEMENT...
 
VIETNAM TAX ISSUES – OUTLOOK ON THE EUROPEAN UNION VIETNAM FREE TRADE AGREEME...
VIETNAM TAX ISSUES – OUTLOOK ON THE EUROPEAN UNION VIETNAM FREE TRADE AGREEME...VIETNAM TAX ISSUES – OUTLOOK ON THE EUROPEAN UNION VIETNAM FREE TRADE AGREEME...
VIETNAM TAX ISSUES – OUTLOOK ON THE EUROPEAN UNION VIETNAM FREE TRADE AGREEME...
 
MEXICO’S 2014 TAX REFORM: A BRIEF REVIEW OF SOME OF ITS MOST RELEVANT ISSUES
MEXICO’S 2014 TAX REFORM: A BRIEF REVIEW OF SOME OF ITS MOST RELEVANT ISSUESMEXICO’S 2014 TAX REFORM: A BRIEF REVIEW OF SOME OF ITS MOST RELEVANT ISSUES
MEXICO’S 2014 TAX REFORM: A BRIEF REVIEW OF SOME OF ITS MOST RELEVANT ISSUES
 
Permanent Establishment May Not Be So Permanent (Prepare for Change)
Permanent Establishment May Not Be So Permanent (Prepare for Change)Permanent Establishment May Not Be So Permanent (Prepare for Change)
Permanent Establishment May Not Be So Permanent (Prepare for Change)
 
The csll and the substantive scope of brazilian tax treaties
The csll and the substantive scope of brazilian tax treatiesThe csll and the substantive scope of brazilian tax treaties
The csll and the substantive scope of brazilian tax treaties
 
Global Indirect Tax Outlook - 2017 and Beyond
Global Indirect Tax Outlook - 2017 and BeyondGlobal Indirect Tax Outlook - 2017 and Beyond
Global Indirect Tax Outlook - 2017 and Beyond
 
Diverted Profits Tax (a) Google Tax: United Kingdom’s combat against tax evasion
Diverted Profits Tax (a) Google Tax: United Kingdom’s combat against tax evasionDiverted Profits Tax (a) Google Tax: United Kingdom’s combat against tax evasion
Diverted Profits Tax (a) Google Tax: United Kingdom’s combat against tax evasion
 
Base Erosion and Profit Shifting - An overview
Base Erosion and Profit Shifting - An overviewBase Erosion and Profit Shifting - An overview
Base Erosion and Profit Shifting - An overview
 
Base Erosion Profit Shifting_Overview
Base Erosion Profit Shifting_Overview Base Erosion Profit Shifting_Overview
Base Erosion Profit Shifting_Overview
 
Vietnam – Taxation – 2015
Vietnam – Taxation – 2015Vietnam – Taxation – 2015
Vietnam – Taxation – 2015
 
Corporate Sustainability Due Diligence Directive (CSDDD or the EU Supply Chai...
Corporate Sustainability Due Diligence Directive (CSDDD or the EU Supply Chai...Corporate Sustainability Due Diligence Directive (CSDDD or the EU Supply Chai...
Corporate Sustainability Due Diligence Directive (CSDDD or the EU Supply Chai...
 
Briefing Paper: Mini One-Stop-Shop
Briefing Paper: Mini One-Stop-ShopBriefing Paper: Mini One-Stop-Shop
Briefing Paper: Mini One-Stop-Shop
 
VIETNAM – LATEST GUIDE TO CONTRACT MANUFACTURING AND TOLLING AGREEMENTS
VIETNAM – LATEST GUIDE TO CONTRACT MANUFACTURING AND TOLLING AGREEMENTSVIETNAM – LATEST GUIDE TO CONTRACT MANUFACTURING AND TOLLING AGREEMENTS
VIETNAM – LATEST GUIDE TO CONTRACT MANUFACTURING AND TOLLING AGREEMENTS
 
International tax newsletter september 2017 - Kreston International
International tax newsletter   september 2017 - Kreston InternationalInternational tax newsletter   september 2017 - Kreston International
International tax newsletter september 2017 - Kreston International
 

Mais de Ramon Tomazela

Tributação e Economia Digital: OCDE, EU e Brasil
Tributação e Economia Digital: OCDE, EU e BrasilTributação e Economia Digital: OCDE, EU e Brasil
Tributação e Economia Digital: OCDE, EU e BrasilRamon Tomazela
 
A competividade no mercado global e a migração para regimes territoriais
A competividade no mercado global e a migração para regimes territoriaisA competividade no mercado global e a migração para regimes territoriais
A competividade no mercado global e a migração para regimes territoriaisRamon Tomazela
 
Transfer Pricing Dispute Resolution in Brazil
Transfer Pricing Dispute Resolution in BrazilTransfer Pricing Dispute Resolution in Brazil
Transfer Pricing Dispute Resolution in BrazilRamon Tomazela
 
A Convenção Multilateral da OCDE e a Ação 15 do Projeto BEPS
A Convenção Multilateral da OCDE e a Ação 15 do Projeto BEPSA Convenção Multilateral da OCDE e a Ação 15 do Projeto BEPS
A Convenção Multilateral da OCDE e a Ação 15 do Projeto BEPSRamon Tomazela
 
Territorial Tax Systems: Motivations and Key Considerations For Effective Change
Territorial Tax Systems: Motivations and Key Considerations For Effective ChangeTerritorial Tax Systems: Motivations and Key Considerations For Effective Change
Territorial Tax Systems: Motivations and Key Considerations For Effective ChangeRamon Tomazela
 
Preços de Transferência e Aplicações Financeiras
Preços de Transferência e Aplicações FinanceirasPreços de Transferência e Aplicações Financeiras
Preços de Transferência e Aplicações FinanceirasRamon Tomazela
 
A Cláusula de Não Discriminação nos Acordos de Bitributação
A Cláusula de Não Discriminação nos Acordos de BitributaçãoA Cláusula de Não Discriminação nos Acordos de Bitributação
A Cláusula de Não Discriminação nos Acordos de BitributaçãoRamon Tomazela
 
A Ação 3 do Projeto BEPS e o regime brasileiro de tributação em bases univers...
A Ação 3 do Projeto BEPS e o regime brasileiro de tributação em bases univers...A Ação 3 do Projeto BEPS e o regime brasileiro de tributação em bases univers...
A Ação 3 do Projeto BEPS e o regime brasileiro de tributação em bases univers...Ramon Tomazela
 
Curso de extensão e aperfeiçoamento em Direito Tributário Internacional - IBDT
Curso de extensão e aperfeiçoamento em Direito Tributário Internacional - IBDTCurso de extensão e aperfeiçoamento em Direito Tributário Internacional - IBDT
Curso de extensão e aperfeiçoamento em Direito Tributário Internacional - IBDTRamon Tomazela
 
US Tax Reform: The Potential Tax Implications for Brazilian Taxpayers
US Tax Reform: The Potential Tax Implications for Brazilian TaxpayersUS Tax Reform: The Potential Tax Implications for Brazilian Taxpayers
US Tax Reform: The Potential Tax Implications for Brazilian TaxpayersRamon Tomazela
 
A Declaração País-a-País e a Ação 13 do Projeto BEPS
A Declaração País-a-País e a Ação 13 do Projeto BEPSA Declaração País-a-País e a Ação 13 do Projeto BEPS
A Declaração País-a-País e a Ação 13 do Projeto BEPSRamon Tomazela
 
Tax Sovereignty and Digital Economy in Post-BEPS Times
Tax Sovereignty and Digital Economy in Post-BEPS TimesTax Sovereignty and Digital Economy in Post-BEPS Times
Tax Sovereignty and Digital Economy in Post-BEPS TimesRamon Tomazela
 
O controle de preços de transferência nas exportações de commodities e o méto...
O controle de preços de transferência nas exportações de commodities e o méto...O controle de preços de transferência nas exportações de commodities e o méto...
O controle de preços de transferência nas exportações de commodities e o méto...Ramon Tomazela
 
A restrição ao aproveitamento do ágio de rentabilidade futura nas operações e...
A restrição ao aproveitamento do ágio de rentabilidade futura nas operações e...A restrição ao aproveitamento do ágio de rentabilidade futura nas operações e...
A restrição ao aproveitamento do ágio de rentabilidade futura nas operações e...Ramon Tomazela
 
O Imposto de Renda e as receitas de frete internacional - Ramon Tomazela e Pa...
O Imposto de Renda e as receitas de frete internacional - Ramon Tomazela e Pa...O Imposto de Renda e as receitas de frete internacional - Ramon Tomazela e Pa...
O Imposto de Renda e as receitas de frete internacional - Ramon Tomazela e Pa...Ramon Tomazela
 
Os Contratos de Licença de Uso de Marca e a Imunidade de PIS e de COFINS sobr...
Os Contratos de Licença de Uso de Marca e a Imunidade de PIS e de COFINS sobr...Os Contratos de Licença de Uso de Marca e a Imunidade de PIS e de COFINS sobr...
Os Contratos de Licença de Uso de Marca e a Imunidade de PIS e de COFINS sobr...Ramon Tomazela
 
RTDA - pagamento de garantia nos acordos de bitributação
RTDA - pagamento de garantia nos acordos de bitributaçãoRTDA - pagamento de garantia nos acordos de bitributação
RTDA - pagamento de garantia nos acordos de bitributaçãoRamon Tomazela
 
O desvirtuamento da teoria do propósito negocial:
O desvirtuamento da teoria do propósito negocial:O desvirtuamento da teoria do propósito negocial:
O desvirtuamento da teoria do propósito negocial:Ramon Tomazela
 
A Mensuração do Ágio na Aquisição de Participação Societária em Pessoa Jurídi...
A Mensuração do Ágio na Aquisição de Participação Societária em Pessoa Jurídi...A Mensuração do Ágio na Aquisição de Participação Societária em Pessoa Jurídi...
A Mensuração do Ágio na Aquisição de Participação Societária em Pessoa Jurídi...Ramon Tomazela
 
O pagamento de juros sobre o capital próprio (JCP) será afetado pela Ação 2 d...
O pagamento de juros sobre o capital próprio (JCP) será afetado pela Ação 2 d...O pagamento de juros sobre o capital próprio (JCP) será afetado pela Ação 2 d...
O pagamento de juros sobre o capital próprio (JCP) será afetado pela Ação 2 d...Ramon Tomazela
 

Mais de Ramon Tomazela (20)

Tributação e Economia Digital: OCDE, EU e Brasil
Tributação e Economia Digital: OCDE, EU e BrasilTributação e Economia Digital: OCDE, EU e Brasil
Tributação e Economia Digital: OCDE, EU e Brasil
 
A competividade no mercado global e a migração para regimes territoriais
A competividade no mercado global e a migração para regimes territoriaisA competividade no mercado global e a migração para regimes territoriais
A competividade no mercado global e a migração para regimes territoriais
 
Transfer Pricing Dispute Resolution in Brazil
Transfer Pricing Dispute Resolution in BrazilTransfer Pricing Dispute Resolution in Brazil
Transfer Pricing Dispute Resolution in Brazil
 
A Convenção Multilateral da OCDE e a Ação 15 do Projeto BEPS
A Convenção Multilateral da OCDE e a Ação 15 do Projeto BEPSA Convenção Multilateral da OCDE e a Ação 15 do Projeto BEPS
A Convenção Multilateral da OCDE e a Ação 15 do Projeto BEPS
 
Territorial Tax Systems: Motivations and Key Considerations For Effective Change
Territorial Tax Systems: Motivations and Key Considerations For Effective ChangeTerritorial Tax Systems: Motivations and Key Considerations For Effective Change
Territorial Tax Systems: Motivations and Key Considerations For Effective Change
 
Preços de Transferência e Aplicações Financeiras
Preços de Transferência e Aplicações FinanceirasPreços de Transferência e Aplicações Financeiras
Preços de Transferência e Aplicações Financeiras
 
A Cláusula de Não Discriminação nos Acordos de Bitributação
A Cláusula de Não Discriminação nos Acordos de BitributaçãoA Cláusula de Não Discriminação nos Acordos de Bitributação
A Cláusula de Não Discriminação nos Acordos de Bitributação
 
A Ação 3 do Projeto BEPS e o regime brasileiro de tributação em bases univers...
A Ação 3 do Projeto BEPS e o regime brasileiro de tributação em bases univers...A Ação 3 do Projeto BEPS e o regime brasileiro de tributação em bases univers...
A Ação 3 do Projeto BEPS e o regime brasileiro de tributação em bases univers...
 
Curso de extensão e aperfeiçoamento em Direito Tributário Internacional - IBDT
Curso de extensão e aperfeiçoamento em Direito Tributário Internacional - IBDTCurso de extensão e aperfeiçoamento em Direito Tributário Internacional - IBDT
Curso de extensão e aperfeiçoamento em Direito Tributário Internacional - IBDT
 
US Tax Reform: The Potential Tax Implications for Brazilian Taxpayers
US Tax Reform: The Potential Tax Implications for Brazilian TaxpayersUS Tax Reform: The Potential Tax Implications for Brazilian Taxpayers
US Tax Reform: The Potential Tax Implications for Brazilian Taxpayers
 
A Declaração País-a-País e a Ação 13 do Projeto BEPS
A Declaração País-a-País e a Ação 13 do Projeto BEPSA Declaração País-a-País e a Ação 13 do Projeto BEPS
A Declaração País-a-País e a Ação 13 do Projeto BEPS
 
Tax Sovereignty and Digital Economy in Post-BEPS Times
Tax Sovereignty and Digital Economy in Post-BEPS TimesTax Sovereignty and Digital Economy in Post-BEPS Times
Tax Sovereignty and Digital Economy in Post-BEPS Times
 
O controle de preços de transferência nas exportações de commodities e o méto...
O controle de preços de transferência nas exportações de commodities e o méto...O controle de preços de transferência nas exportações de commodities e o méto...
O controle de preços de transferência nas exportações de commodities e o méto...
 
A restrição ao aproveitamento do ágio de rentabilidade futura nas operações e...
A restrição ao aproveitamento do ágio de rentabilidade futura nas operações e...A restrição ao aproveitamento do ágio de rentabilidade futura nas operações e...
A restrição ao aproveitamento do ágio de rentabilidade futura nas operações e...
 
O Imposto de Renda e as receitas de frete internacional - Ramon Tomazela e Pa...
O Imposto de Renda e as receitas de frete internacional - Ramon Tomazela e Pa...O Imposto de Renda e as receitas de frete internacional - Ramon Tomazela e Pa...
O Imposto de Renda e as receitas de frete internacional - Ramon Tomazela e Pa...
 
Os Contratos de Licença de Uso de Marca e a Imunidade de PIS e de COFINS sobr...
Os Contratos de Licença de Uso de Marca e a Imunidade de PIS e de COFINS sobr...Os Contratos de Licença de Uso de Marca e a Imunidade de PIS e de COFINS sobr...
Os Contratos de Licença de Uso de Marca e a Imunidade de PIS e de COFINS sobr...
 
RTDA - pagamento de garantia nos acordos de bitributação
RTDA - pagamento de garantia nos acordos de bitributaçãoRTDA - pagamento de garantia nos acordos de bitributação
RTDA - pagamento de garantia nos acordos de bitributação
 
O desvirtuamento da teoria do propósito negocial:
O desvirtuamento da teoria do propósito negocial:O desvirtuamento da teoria do propósito negocial:
O desvirtuamento da teoria do propósito negocial:
 
A Mensuração do Ágio na Aquisição de Participação Societária em Pessoa Jurídi...
A Mensuração do Ágio na Aquisição de Participação Societária em Pessoa Jurídi...A Mensuração do Ágio na Aquisição de Participação Societária em Pessoa Jurídi...
A Mensuração do Ágio na Aquisição de Participação Societária em Pessoa Jurídi...
 
O pagamento de juros sobre o capital próprio (JCP) será afetado pela Ação 2 d...
O pagamento de juros sobre o capital próprio (JCP) será afetado pela Ação 2 d...O pagamento de juros sobre o capital próprio (JCP) será afetado pela Ação 2 d...
O pagamento de juros sobre o capital próprio (JCP) será afetado pela Ação 2 d...
 

Último

BPA GROUP 7 - DARIO VS. MISON REPORTING.pdf
BPA GROUP 7 - DARIO VS. MISON REPORTING.pdfBPA GROUP 7 - DARIO VS. MISON REPORTING.pdf
BPA GROUP 7 - DARIO VS. MISON REPORTING.pdflaysamaeguardiano
 
6th sem cpc notes for 6th semester students samjhe. Padhlo bhai
6th sem cpc notes for 6th semester students samjhe. Padhlo bhai6th sem cpc notes for 6th semester students samjhe. Padhlo bhai
6th sem cpc notes for 6th semester students samjhe. Padhlo bhaiShashankKumar441258
 
一比一原版利兹大学毕业证学位证书
一比一原版利兹大学毕业证学位证书一比一原版利兹大学毕业证学位证书
一比一原版利兹大学毕业证学位证书E LSS
 
LITERAL RULE OF INTERPRETATION - PRIMARY RULE
LITERAL RULE OF INTERPRETATION - PRIMARY RULELITERAL RULE OF INTERPRETATION - PRIMARY RULE
LITERAL RULE OF INTERPRETATION - PRIMARY RULEsreeramsaipranitha
 
如何办理(SFSta文凭证书)美国旧金山州立大学毕业证学位证书
如何办理(SFSta文凭证书)美国旧金山州立大学毕业证学位证书如何办理(SFSta文凭证书)美国旧金山州立大学毕业证学位证书
如何办理(SFSta文凭证书)美国旧金山州立大学毕业证学位证书Fs Las
 
Divorce Procedure in India (Info) (1).pdf
Divorce Procedure in India (Info) (1).pdfDivorce Procedure in India (Info) (1).pdf
Divorce Procedure in India (Info) (1).pdfdigitalnikesh24
 
CALL ON ➥8923113531 🔝Call Girls Singar Nagar Lucknow best sexual service
CALL ON ➥8923113531 🔝Call Girls Singar Nagar Lucknow best sexual serviceCALL ON ➥8923113531 🔝Call Girls Singar Nagar Lucknow best sexual service
CALL ON ➥8923113531 🔝Call Girls Singar Nagar Lucknow best sexual serviceanilsa9823
 
Andrea Hill Featured in Canadian Lawyer as SkyLaw Recognized as a Top Boutique
Andrea Hill Featured in Canadian Lawyer as SkyLaw Recognized as a Top BoutiqueAndrea Hill Featured in Canadian Lawyer as SkyLaw Recognized as a Top Boutique
Andrea Hill Featured in Canadian Lawyer as SkyLaw Recognized as a Top BoutiqueSkyLaw Professional Corporation
 
WhatsApp 📞 8448380779 ✅Call Girls In Nangli Wazidpur Sector 135 ( Noida)
WhatsApp 📞 8448380779 ✅Call Girls In Nangli Wazidpur Sector 135 ( Noida)WhatsApp 📞 8448380779 ✅Call Girls In Nangli Wazidpur Sector 135 ( Noida)
WhatsApp 📞 8448380779 ✅Call Girls In Nangli Wazidpur Sector 135 ( Noida)Delhi Call girls
 
CAFC Chronicles: Costly Tales of Claim Construction Fails
CAFC Chronicles: Costly Tales of Claim Construction FailsCAFC Chronicles: Costly Tales of Claim Construction Fails
CAFC Chronicles: Costly Tales of Claim Construction FailsAurora Consulting
 
一比一原版西澳大学毕业证学位证书
 一比一原版西澳大学毕业证学位证书 一比一原版西澳大学毕业证学位证书
一比一原版西澳大学毕业证学位证书SS A
 
INVOLUNTARY TRANSFERS Kenya school of law.pptx
INVOLUNTARY TRANSFERS Kenya school of law.pptxINVOLUNTARY TRANSFERS Kenya school of law.pptx
INVOLUNTARY TRANSFERS Kenya school of law.pptxnyabatejosphat1
 
Introduction to Corruption, definition, types, impact and conclusion
Introduction to Corruption, definition, types, impact and conclusionIntroduction to Corruption, definition, types, impact and conclusion
Introduction to Corruption, definition, types, impact and conclusionAnuragMishra811030
 
如何办理(Lincoln文凭证书)林肯大学毕业证学位证书
如何办理(Lincoln文凭证书)林肯大学毕业证学位证书如何办理(Lincoln文凭证书)林肯大学毕业证学位证书
如何办理(Lincoln文凭证书)林肯大学毕业证学位证书Fs Las
 
如何办理(USF文凭证书)美国旧金山大学毕业证学位证书
如何办理(USF文凭证书)美国旧金山大学毕业证学位证书如何办理(USF文凭证书)美国旧金山大学毕业证学位证书
如何办理(USF文凭证书)美国旧金山大学毕业证学位证书Fs Las
 
如何办理(MSU文凭证书)密歇根州立大学毕业证学位证书
 如何办理(MSU文凭证书)密歇根州立大学毕业证学位证书 如何办理(MSU文凭证书)密歇根州立大学毕业证学位证书
如何办理(MSU文凭证书)密歇根州立大学毕业证学位证书Sir Lt
 
Chp 1- Contract and its kinds-business law .ppt
Chp 1- Contract and its kinds-business law .pptChp 1- Contract and its kinds-business law .ppt
Chp 1- Contract and its kinds-business law .pptzainabbkhaleeq123
 
THE FACTORIES ACT,1948 (2).pptx labour
THE FACTORIES ACT,1948 (2).pptx   labourTHE FACTORIES ACT,1948 (2).pptx   labour
THE FACTORIES ACT,1948 (2).pptx labourBhavikaGholap1
 
PPT- Voluntary Liquidation (Under section 59).pptx
PPT- Voluntary Liquidation (Under section 59).pptxPPT- Voluntary Liquidation (Under section 59).pptx
PPT- Voluntary Liquidation (Under section 59).pptxRRR Chambers
 
Municipal-Council-Ratlam-vs-Vardi-Chand-A-Landmark-Writ-Case.pptx
Municipal-Council-Ratlam-vs-Vardi-Chand-A-Landmark-Writ-Case.pptxMunicipal-Council-Ratlam-vs-Vardi-Chand-A-Landmark-Writ-Case.pptx
Municipal-Council-Ratlam-vs-Vardi-Chand-A-Landmark-Writ-Case.pptxSHIVAMGUPTA671167
 

Último (20)

BPA GROUP 7 - DARIO VS. MISON REPORTING.pdf
BPA GROUP 7 - DARIO VS. MISON REPORTING.pdfBPA GROUP 7 - DARIO VS. MISON REPORTING.pdf
BPA GROUP 7 - DARIO VS. MISON REPORTING.pdf
 
6th sem cpc notes for 6th semester students samjhe. Padhlo bhai
6th sem cpc notes for 6th semester students samjhe. Padhlo bhai6th sem cpc notes for 6th semester students samjhe. Padhlo bhai
6th sem cpc notes for 6th semester students samjhe. Padhlo bhai
 
一比一原版利兹大学毕业证学位证书
一比一原版利兹大学毕业证学位证书一比一原版利兹大学毕业证学位证书
一比一原版利兹大学毕业证学位证书
 
LITERAL RULE OF INTERPRETATION - PRIMARY RULE
LITERAL RULE OF INTERPRETATION - PRIMARY RULELITERAL RULE OF INTERPRETATION - PRIMARY RULE
LITERAL RULE OF INTERPRETATION - PRIMARY RULE
 
如何办理(SFSta文凭证书)美国旧金山州立大学毕业证学位证书
如何办理(SFSta文凭证书)美国旧金山州立大学毕业证学位证书如何办理(SFSta文凭证书)美国旧金山州立大学毕业证学位证书
如何办理(SFSta文凭证书)美国旧金山州立大学毕业证学位证书
 
Divorce Procedure in India (Info) (1).pdf
Divorce Procedure in India (Info) (1).pdfDivorce Procedure in India (Info) (1).pdf
Divorce Procedure in India (Info) (1).pdf
 
CALL ON ➥8923113531 🔝Call Girls Singar Nagar Lucknow best sexual service
CALL ON ➥8923113531 🔝Call Girls Singar Nagar Lucknow best sexual serviceCALL ON ➥8923113531 🔝Call Girls Singar Nagar Lucknow best sexual service
CALL ON ➥8923113531 🔝Call Girls Singar Nagar Lucknow best sexual service
 
Andrea Hill Featured in Canadian Lawyer as SkyLaw Recognized as a Top Boutique
Andrea Hill Featured in Canadian Lawyer as SkyLaw Recognized as a Top BoutiqueAndrea Hill Featured in Canadian Lawyer as SkyLaw Recognized as a Top Boutique
Andrea Hill Featured in Canadian Lawyer as SkyLaw Recognized as a Top Boutique
 
WhatsApp 📞 8448380779 ✅Call Girls In Nangli Wazidpur Sector 135 ( Noida)
WhatsApp 📞 8448380779 ✅Call Girls In Nangli Wazidpur Sector 135 ( Noida)WhatsApp 📞 8448380779 ✅Call Girls In Nangli Wazidpur Sector 135 ( Noida)
WhatsApp 📞 8448380779 ✅Call Girls In Nangli Wazidpur Sector 135 ( Noida)
 
CAFC Chronicles: Costly Tales of Claim Construction Fails
CAFC Chronicles: Costly Tales of Claim Construction FailsCAFC Chronicles: Costly Tales of Claim Construction Fails
CAFC Chronicles: Costly Tales of Claim Construction Fails
 
一比一原版西澳大学毕业证学位证书
 一比一原版西澳大学毕业证学位证书 一比一原版西澳大学毕业证学位证书
一比一原版西澳大学毕业证学位证书
 
INVOLUNTARY TRANSFERS Kenya school of law.pptx
INVOLUNTARY TRANSFERS Kenya school of law.pptxINVOLUNTARY TRANSFERS Kenya school of law.pptx
INVOLUNTARY TRANSFERS Kenya school of law.pptx
 
Introduction to Corruption, definition, types, impact and conclusion
Introduction to Corruption, definition, types, impact and conclusionIntroduction to Corruption, definition, types, impact and conclusion
Introduction to Corruption, definition, types, impact and conclusion
 
如何办理(Lincoln文凭证书)林肯大学毕业证学位证书
如何办理(Lincoln文凭证书)林肯大学毕业证学位证书如何办理(Lincoln文凭证书)林肯大学毕业证学位证书
如何办理(Lincoln文凭证书)林肯大学毕业证学位证书
 
如何办理(USF文凭证书)美国旧金山大学毕业证学位证书
如何办理(USF文凭证书)美国旧金山大学毕业证学位证书如何办理(USF文凭证书)美国旧金山大学毕业证学位证书
如何办理(USF文凭证书)美国旧金山大学毕业证学位证书
 
如何办理(MSU文凭证书)密歇根州立大学毕业证学位证书
 如何办理(MSU文凭证书)密歇根州立大学毕业证学位证书 如何办理(MSU文凭证书)密歇根州立大学毕业证学位证书
如何办理(MSU文凭证书)密歇根州立大学毕业证学位证书
 
Chp 1- Contract and its kinds-business law .ppt
Chp 1- Contract and its kinds-business law .pptChp 1- Contract and its kinds-business law .ppt
Chp 1- Contract and its kinds-business law .ppt
 
THE FACTORIES ACT,1948 (2).pptx labour
THE FACTORIES ACT,1948 (2).pptx   labourTHE FACTORIES ACT,1948 (2).pptx   labour
THE FACTORIES ACT,1948 (2).pptx labour
 
PPT- Voluntary Liquidation (Under section 59).pptx
PPT- Voluntary Liquidation (Under section 59).pptxPPT- Voluntary Liquidation (Under section 59).pptx
PPT- Voluntary Liquidation (Under section 59).pptx
 
Municipal-Council-Ratlam-vs-Vardi-Chand-A-Landmark-Writ-Case.pptx
Municipal-Council-Ratlam-vs-Vardi-Chand-A-Landmark-Writ-Case.pptxMunicipal-Council-Ratlam-vs-Vardi-Chand-A-Landmark-Writ-Case.pptx
Municipal-Council-Ratlam-vs-Vardi-Chand-A-Landmark-Writ-Case.pptx
 

The United Kingdom’ s Diverted Profits Tax and Tax Treaties: An Evaluation

  • 1. 399© IBFD BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION JULY 2016 The United Kingdom’ s Diverted Profits Tax and Tax Treaties: An Evaluation This article examines the diverted profits tax (DPT) introduced by the United Kingdom to counter aggressive tax planning adopted by many multinational enterprises so as to transfer profits from its jurisdiction, and the main controversies surrounding the compatibility of the DPT with tax treaties. 1. Introduction InApril2015,theUnitedKingdomintroducedthediverted profits tax (DPT) into its domestic law. The DPT has the declared objective of countering aggressive tax planning as used by many multinational enterprises (MNEs) to transfer profits from the United Kingdom’ s jurisdiction by way of business structures that prevent the charac- terization of a permanent establishment (PE) within the United Kingdom, either by the use artificial transactions or of entities without economic substance. This article deals specifically with the DPT levied when a foreign company carries on activities in the United Kingdom by means of a structure that is designed to avoid the creation of a PE, i.e. a taxable presence, in the United Kingdom. In such circumstances, the DPT targets situ- ations where a non-resident company provides goods, ser- vices or other properties in the United Kingdom through a business model that avoids the characterization of a PE.1 The DPT is levied at a rate of 25%, which is higher than the current standard corporation tax rate of 20% levied in the United Kingdom. The tax base corresponds to the profits that would have been attributed to the PE if its presence had not been prevented by the taxpayer. The profits to be subject to the DPT are calculated using the same domestic taxrulesthatgoverntheallocationofprofitstoPEslocated in the United Kingdom. TheDPTmaybeconsideredthegreatestproofofinconsist- ency in the attitude of certain European countries regard- ing the debate on the allocation of taxing rights between the source state and the residence state. In the recent past, the main argument used by developed countries against the taxation at source of technical services and adminis- trative assistance was the absence of a PE in the source * MasterofLaws(LL.M.)ininternationaltaxation,ViennaWirtschafts- universität Wien (University of Economics and Business, WU) and Master of Laws candidate in tax law, University of São Paulo (USP), Member of the Scientific Committee, postgraduate course in interna- tionaltaxlawoftheBrazilianInstituteofTaxLaw(IBDT)andVisiting Professor,postgraduatecoursesinBrazil,andTaxAssociate,Marizde Oliveira e Siqueira Campos Advogados. The author can be contacted at rts@marizsiqueira.com.br 1. UK: Finance Act 2015, sec. 86. state, thereby being able to demonstrate the existence of an effective connection with its jurisdiction. However, as soon as some US MNEs started to sell their products in the UK consumer market without paying a supposedly “fair share of tax”, the United Kingdom quickly introduced the DPT into its national tax system to ensure the taxation of a portion of the profit derived by such MNEs in its territory. Despiteallreasonablejustificationsfortheadoptionofthis unilateral tax measure, which departs from the proposals presented by the OECD Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (BEPS) initiative,2 the compatibility of the DPT with tax treaties is very questionable. 2. The DPT and the Material Scope of Tax Treaties As reported, the UK government decided to implement a new tax levied on diverted profits with the deliberate intentionofexcludingthetaxfromthematerialscopeofits tax treaties. However, regardless of the unilateral position adopted by the UK government, the DPT should be exam- ined carefully to verify whether it falls within tax treaties based on the OECD Model.3 In this context, it should be noted that article 2 of the OECD Model, which deals with the taxes covered by a tax treaty, reads as follows: 1. This convention shall apply to taxes on income and on capital imposed on behalf of a Contract- ing State or of its political subdivisions or local authorities, irrespective of the manner in which they are levied. 2. There shall be regarded as taxes on income and on capital all taxes imposed on total income, on totalcapital,oronelementsofincomeorofcapital, including taxed on gains from the alienation of movableorimmovableproperty,taxedonthetotal amounts of wages or salaries paid by enterprises, as well as taxes on capital appreciation. (...) 4. TheConventionshallapplyalsotoanyidenticalor substantially similar taxes that are imposed after the date of signature of the Convention in addi- tion to, or in place of, the existing taxes. The com- petent authorities of the Contracting States shall 2. See, for example, OECD, Addressing Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (OECD 2013), International Organizations’ Documentation IBFD and OECD, Action Plan on Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (OECD 2013), In- ternational Organizations’ Documentation IBFD. 3. Most recently, OECD Model Tax Convention on Income and on Capital (26 July 2014), Models IBFD. Ramon Tomazela Santos*International/United Kingdom Exported / Printed on 20 July 2016 by biblio2@ibdt.org.br.
  • 2. 400 BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION JULY 2016 © IBFD Ramon Tomazela Santos notify each other of any significant changes that have been made in their taxation laws. As can be seen, article 2 of the OECD Model covers any taxes levied on total income or on specific types of income earned by taxpayers, regardless of the political subdivision in state and the method of collection, for example, income tax withheld at source or income tax levied on the basis of a tax return. In addition, identical or substantially similar taxes imposed after the date of the signature of the tax treaty are also covered in article 2(4) of the OECD Model. Indeed, this provision contains an extension clause, which encom- passes taxes introduced after the conclusion of a tax treaty if they are identical or substantially similar to the taxes originally covered. Such an extension clause preserves the application of a tax treaty over the time, as it avoids the fact that amendments to domestic laws make a tax treaty inoperative. It also relieves the contracting states from the obligation of renegotiating a tax treaty on each modification of their domestic laws. Consequently, if the new taxes imposed are identical or substantially similar to those covered by the tax treaty, the levying of such tax should comply with the treaty provisions agreed by the contracting states.4 In general, the term “tax” means any charge levied by an authority of a sovereign state on a person or property underitsjurisdictiontoobtainfinancialresourcestocover general public expenditure.5 As a result, the term “tax” has a broad and generic meaning that encompasses almost all amounts levied by a state based on its sovereignty, with a few exceptions, such as the charges relating to administra- tive policing powers, which are often referred to as “fees”. All others forms of taxation, such as duties, excises and socialcontributions,maybeincludedinthebroadconcept of “tax”. Specifically with regard to the income tax, article 2(2) of the OECD Model adopts a very broad wording, which covers not only a comprehensive income tax levied on the total income earned by a taxpayer, but also specific taxes that are levied on particular types of income.6 Appar- ently, this broad definition could apply to the DPT levied ontheprofitsdivertedfromtheUnitedKingdom’ smarket. In contrast, it could be argued that the DPT is not sub- stantially similar to income tax, as it has a specific scope that encompasses a narrow number of taxpayers, as well as a different tax rate. However, article 2(2) of the OECD Model also covers tax levied on elements of income, such as in a schedular income tax system, in which separate taxes are imposed on different categories of income. In addition, the applicable tax rate is not a decisive element in defining whether a new tax is covered by article 2 of the OECD Model, as it only quantifies the amount to be paid to the government treasury, without determining the legal nature of the tax due. 4. M.Lang,Introduction to the Law of Double Taxation Conventions,2ndedn., sec. 8. (IBFD/Linde 2013), Online Books IBFD. 5. A. Sampaio de Moraes Godoy, Direito Tributário International Contextu- alizado pp. 28-119 (Quartier Latin 2009). 6. J. Hortalá i Vallvé, Comentarios a la Red Española de Convenios de Doble Imposición pp. 65-66 (Thomson/Aranzadi 2007). Further, the definition of PE is directly connected with article 7 of tax treaties, which is the allocation rule applied to business profits. As a consequence, if a country creates a new type of tax that is levied on PEs, or on MNEs that avoided the creation of a PE, on diverted profits, such a tax would clearly fall within the material scope of tax treaties. In the case under consideration, even the name of the new tax indicates that it is levied on profits. Strictly, the DPT is substantially similar to an income tax, as its tax base corresponds exactly to the profits that would havebeenattributedtoaPEhadataxpayerhadnotavoided such a characterization in the United Kingdom. The tax base is usually considered to be the most important factor in identifying the similarities between new taxes and taxes covered by article 2 of tax treaties. As a result, given the similarities in the computation rules, it would appear that the differences between the DPT and the regular income tax levied on a PE in the United Kingdom are not so great as to prevent the DPT from being regarded as a tax sub- stantially similar to the income tax. It follows that, despite themanoeuvreusedbytheUnitedKingdomtoimplement a new tax, the DPT is covered by the material scope of its tax treaties. 3. The DPT and the Equivalent of Article 7 of the OECD Model in Tax Treaties Assuming that the DPT is a substantially similar tax, the question to be answered concerns its compatibility with article 7 of tax treaties based on the OECD Model, given that the United Kingdom intends to tax profits earned by a non-resident company, regardless of the effective char- acterization of a PE in its jurisdiction. In other words, the question that arises is whether, in the event that the non- resident company is headquartered in a state that has con- cluded a tax treaty with the United Kingdom, the UK gov- ernment may levy the DPT on profits allegedly diverted, even without the effective characterization of a PE within the state. Article 7(1) of the OECD Model, as adopted by the United Kingdom in most of its tax treaties, reads as follows: Profits of an enterprise of a Contracting States shall be taxable only in that State unless the enterprise carries on business in the other Contracting State through a permanent establishment sit- uated therein. If the enterprise carries on business as aforesaid, the profits that are attributable to the permanent establishment in accordance with the provisions of paragraph 2 may be taxed in that other State. Article 7(1) of tax treaties has the objective scope of pro- tecting the profits earned by individuals or legal entities resident in the other contracting state through the devel- opment of an economic activity.7 Consequently, profits arising from the exercise of a business activity should be taxed exclusively in the residence state. The only excep- tions to this general rule rely on the economic activity per- 7. L.E. Schoueri, The Objective Scope of Article 7 and the Treaty Protection to Deemed Distributed Dividends Kluwer Intl. Tax Blog (2015), available at http://www.kluwertaxlawblog.com/blog/2015/04/27/the-objective- scope-of-article-7-and-the-treaty-protection-to-deemed-distributed- dividends/. Exported / Printed on 20 July 2016 by biblio2@ibdt.org.br.
  • 3. 401© IBFD BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION JULY 2016 The United Kingdom’ s Diverted Profits Tax and Tax Treaties: An Evaluation formed in the source state being undertaken by way of a PE, as well as on the income being classified under specific distributive rules, which establish a specific allocation of the right to tax. It is, therefore, clear that article 7 of the OECD Model has a universal scope, thereby serving as an umbrella for differ- ent types of income derived from business activities. The reason for this is because it covers the results arising from the exercise of an economic activity conducted by a resi- dent of a contracting state (i.e. the residence state) in the other contracting state (i.e. the source state), provided that therelevantincomeisnotexpresslydealtwithinoneofthe specific distributive rules. That is why article 7(1) of the OECD Model may be considered to be the heart of a tax treaty, under which the largest portion of income derived from international economic activities is classified.8 ThedefinitionofPEsetoutinarticle5oftheOECDModel is one of the key concepts in tax treaties for the alloca- tion of taxing rights relating to foreign business activities. This is because the concept of a PE serves as a criterion to legitimate the attribution of the taxing rights to the source state. It also indicates a substantial degree of presence in the economic life of the source state, which justifies the taxation of a foreign person on the profits attributable to the business activity developed in its consumer market, in the same way as a domestic person. Nevertheless, as the wording of the definition of a PE has remained nearly unchanged for the last 50 years,9 new business models developed during the last decades allow taxpayers to derive a high level of income without a physi- cal presence in the host state. MNEs can, therefore, have a significant business presence in the economy of another state, without becoming liable to tax due to the lack of nexus under the current definition of a PE. The DPT is intended to counter the artificial avoidance of the status of a PE. However, the DPT does not appear to differentiatebetweensituationsinwhichataxpayersimply does not have a fixed place of business in the source state over a particular duration of time from those in which a taxpayer effectively makes use of schemes or pre-planned arrangements that are designed to artificially avoid the characterization of a PE in the source state. Article 5 of the OECD Model deals with the following three different types of PEs: (1) a general PE; (2) a con- struction PE; and (3) a dependent agent PE. Each of these definitions of a PE requires the presence of certain ele- ments for its characterization, such as, inter alia: (1) a ter- ritorial link evidenced by a fixed place of business; (2) a time threshold that indicates the level of permanence; and (3) the authority to conclude contracts in the name of the enterprise. All of these concepts and requirements may be usedbythetaxpayertodesignabusinessmodelthatavoids the characterization of a PE in the source state, thereby 8. A. Xavier, Direito tributário internacional do Brasil p. 567 (Forense 2010). 9. A. Storck A. Zeiler, Beyond the OECD Update 2014: Changes to the Con- cepts of Permanent Establishment in the Light of the BEPS Discussion, in The OECD-Model-Convention and its Update 2014 sec. I, p. 242 (M. Lang et al. eds., IBFD/Linde 2015), Online Books IBFD. reducing its tax burden. As a result, the current rules leave room for the use of valid tax planning strategies in rela- tion to the definition of a PE, as new economic activities and technological developments offer a reasonable degree of flexibility for the taxpayers to structure their business without crossing the PE threshold. Article 5(4) of the OECD Model also contains a list of preparatory or auxiliary activities that are to be treated as exceptions to the general definition of a PE, even when a fixed place of business is characterized. Although orig- inally designed for a different economic context, these exemptions are granted by the treaty provision itself. As a result, the simple adoption of a business model that either avoids the characterization of a PE or exploits the exemp- tions for preparatory or auxiliary activities cannot be con- sidered to be the artificial avoidance of the status of a PE. In practice, it is unclear whether the DPT only encom- passes cases where a taxpayer artificially avoids the char- acterization of a PE in the market jurisdiction through the artificial fragmentation of its transaction. As the relevant UK law is drafted in broad terms, it is very likely that the DPT also affects cases in which the taxpayer designs its businessmodeltofallwithinthePEthreshold,butwithout using transactions structured in an artificial manner. In this respect, only artificial structures, instigated exclu- sively for tax purposes and with no economic substance, should be countered by tax authorities. If the structure adopted by a taxpayer is congruent with the business model chosen, the tax authorities cannot dis- regard a valid tax planning strategy just because it reduces the tax liability in the source state. Conversely, when the structure used by the taxpayer does not have a certain degree of economic substance and coherence, the tax authorities may counter it, irrespective of the introduc- tion of a specific tax for that purpose. The problem is that the United Kingdom intends to levy the DPT on international structures adopted by MNEs that were not intended to be covered by the PE definition as originally drafted. Nevertheless, as these structures are not artificial from a legal standpoint, the United Kingdom should, in theory, renegotiate its tax treaties to amend the definition of a PE, instead of levying a new tax. As taxpayers have the right to choose the legal actions and transactions that best fit their needs, the simple fact that the business model adopted falls within the definition of a PE does not, in itself, authorize the collection of a substan- tially similar tax that contradicts the international obliga- tions assumed in a tax treaty. This is why the levying of the DPT should be restricted to cases where the tax authorities can demonstrate the artificiality of the legal structure used by the taxpayer or, at best, the lack of any other plausible justification for the means adopted. Recently, the OECD BEPS initiative has resurrected the debate regarding the adequacy and convenience of the concept of a PE with regard to the allocation of the tax jurisdiction given the very significant pressure exerted by developed countries. In particular, numerous European countries, which have become a major market for many Exported / Printed on 20 July 2016 by biblio2@ibdt.org.br.
  • 4. 402 BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION JULY 2016 © IBFD Ramon Tomazela Santos US MNEs, such as Amazon, Apple, Google and Starbucks, have begun to demand more forcefully their right to tax at least part of the profits derived by such MNEs in their territories. However, the proposals presented in Action 7 of the OECD BEPS initiative reveal an unsuccessful attempt to adapt an outdated concept to a new economic reality, without directly challenging the paradigms of interna- tional taxation.10 Action 7 only targets circumvention of the PE definition, i.e. artificial fragmentation, commis- sionaire arrangements, preparatory or auxiliary exemp- tions, among others, without departing from the current rules on the allocation of taxing rights between contract- ing states. Consequently, as in the vast majority of Action Plans in its BEPS initiative, the OECD has insisted on maintaining the current paradigms of international taxa- tion, in seeking only to adapt outdated concepts to a new economic scenario. The amendment of the PE definition, as envisaged under Action 7 of the OECD BEPS initiative, would most prob- ably not encompass all cases in which foreign enterprises can undertake a substantial level of economic activity in thesourcestatewithoutestablishingthedegreeofpresence required by the PE threshold. Against this background, it is easy to see why the United Kingdom decided to enact the DPT to ensure the taxation of a portion of the profit derived by such MNEs. The United Kingdom probably found the approach followed by the OECD in Action 7 ineffective and, therefore, opted for the introduction of a more radical tax measure that targets profits diverted to other countries. The point is that, despite all possible justifications, the compatibility of the DPT with article 7 of the tax treaties concluded by the United Kingdom is very questionable. The various specific objections to the DPT with regard to tax treaties are now summarized below. First, the rules regarding the DPT do not only apply to cases where the sole or main purpose of the taxpayer is to avoid taxes. This would be essential in characterizing the rule in the DPT as an anti-abuse provision. The use of UK law is a simple mechanism that permits the taxation of any sales or services undertaken in the UK internal market, regardless of the characterization of a PE. This flagrantly contradicts article 7 of the tax treaties. Second, the deemed characterization of a PE based on a domestic anti-abuse rule without the support of the wording in a tax treaty could result in double taxation, as a residence state only grants an exemption or a foreign tax credit in relation to taxes levied in accordance with the distributive rules of a tax treaty. Consequently, the imposi- tion of the DPT by the United Kingdom could result in the double taxation of corporate profits, which is precisely the phenomenon that a tax treaty is intended to avoid. 10. OECD, Action 7 Final Report 2015 – Preventing the Artificial Avoidance of Permanent Establishment Status (OECD 2015), International Organiza- tions’ Documentation IBFD. This demonstrates that the United Kingdom should have extended or amended the definition of a PE in its tax trea- tiestoencompassnewactivitiesdevelopedwithoutaphys- ical presence within the country. The United Kingdom could also have included in its tax treaties specific anti- avoidance rules against common tax planning strategies used to avoid the characterization of a PE. What cannot be agreed to is the introduction of a new tax to cover these situations which violate treaty obligations. The conclusion would be different if the DPT were to be levied only when the taxpayer’ s conduct consisted of con- cealing the existence of a PE in the source state by means of fraudulent manoeuvres. However, as the UK law is drafted in broad terms, it would appear that, in several cases where a structure used by a taxpayer could not be considered to be artificial, the levying of the DPT by the UK tax authori- ties, Her Majesty’ s Revenue Customs (HMRC), would be incompatible with tax treaties. 4. Domestic Anti-Avoidance Rules and Tax Treaties Despite the protection granted by article 7 of the OECD Model, HMRC could argue that the DPT would only be levied in abusive situations involving the requalification of legal structures used by taxpayers as artificially circum- venting the concept of PE. Based on this, HMRC could argue that, with the support of the OECD’ s position on the compatibility of domestic general anti-avoidance rules (GAARs) with treaty provisions, the mere requalification of the facts, to be able to consider that there is a PE in the United Kingdom, would not be affected by tax treaties. This line of reasoning would allow the collection of the DPT even in the face of a tax treaty. In fact, the OECD argues, in the Commentary on Article 1 of the OECD Model, that: ... to the extent these anti-avoidance rules are part of the basic domestic rules set by domestic tax laws for determining which facts give rise to a tax liability, they are not addressed in tax trea- ties and therefore not affected by them. Thus, as a general rule, there will be no conflict between such rules and the provisions of tax conventions.11 ThisinterpretationofthecompatibilityofdomesticGAARs with the tax treaties, which is reinforced in the Commen- tary on Article 1 of the OECD Model,12 is adopted by most OECD member countries. The only exceptions are Lux- embourg, the Netherlands and Switzerland, which have recorded observations against such a questionable inter- pretation as proposed by the OECD.13 This is not the place to review this subject in all of its vari- eties. It is, however, important to present brief comments regarding the position of the OECD on the compatibility of domestic GAARs with treaty provisions. Initially, it should be emphasized that the title of and the preamble to tax treaties includes the purpose of avoiding 11. OECD Model Tax Convention on Income and on Capital: Commentary on Article 1, para. 9.2 (26 July 2014), Models IBFD. 12. Id., at paras. 22.1 and 23. 13. Id., at paras. 27.6, 27.7 and 27.9. Exported / Printed on 20 July 2016 by biblio2@ibdt.org.br.
  • 5. 403© IBFD BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION JULY 2016 The United Kingdom’ s Diverted Profits Tax and Tax Treaties: An Evaluation double taxation and the prevention of tax evasion. As a result, even if a prescriptive content is assigned to the pre- amble of tax treaties, it is clear that domestic anti-abuse rules may only be applied in conflict with the provisions of tax treaties in the event of demonstrable tax evasion,14 but not in the case of tax avoidance or tax mitigation. The passages of the Commentaries on the OECD Model that use the term “tax avoidance” are mainly related to the exchange of information and administrative assistance in the collection of taxes. Consequently, it is not possible to include the efforts aimed at tax avoidance as a general objective of tax treaties, which should guide the interpre- tation of their provisions, in the light of article 31(1) of the Vienna Convention on the Law of Treaties (the Vienna Convention) (1969).15 In addition, in other passages that refer to the need to counter tax avoidance, it has been expressly decided to include specific anti-avoidance measures in the OECD Model, such as: (1) the concept of beneficial owner in art- icles 10 (Dividends), 11 (Interest) and 12 (Royalties); (2) the replacement of the expression “each fiscal year” with “any twelve month period” in article 15 (Income from employment); and (3) the inclusion of article 17(2) (Enter- tainers and Sportspersons), which permits the taxation at source of income attributed to star companies, regardless of the use of an artificial structure by the entertainer or sportsperson. These examples demonstrate that, in order to deal with tax avoidance, states should amend the wording of treaty provisions to prevent their circumvention by taxpayers by way of tax planning, rather than simply implement domestic anti-avoidance rules that overlap with the obli- gations assumed at an international level, which consti- tutes a treaty override.16 The application of domestic anti-avoidance rules may also result in an unilateral change of a tax treatment granted by a tax treaty, as the tax obligation created by the domestic law of a contracting state, based on its interaction with the domesticanti-avoidancerules,maymodifyorfrustratethe effects that could have been derived from the application of the tax treaty.17 This is precisely what may happen in the case under analysis, as the DPT as levied by the United Kingdom frustrates the typical effects derived from article 7 of the OECD Model, which provides for the exclusive taxation of business profits in the residence state, except where a PE can be characterized in the source state, which does not occur in the case of the DPT. In addition, the position expressed by the OECD in para- graph 9.2 of the Commentary on Article 1 of the OECD 14. G. Maisto, Domestic Anti-Abuse Rules and Bilateral Tax Conventions in the Light of Public International Law, in Essays on Tax Treaties A Tribute to David A. Ward pp. 334/335 (G. Maisto, A. Nikolakakis J.M. Ulmer eds., IBFD/CTF 2012). 15. UNViennaConventionontheLawofTreaties(23May1969),TreatiesIBFD. 16. With regard to treaty override, see L.E. Schoueri, Tax Treaty Override A Jurisdictional Approach, 42 Intertax 11 (2014) and C. de Pietro, Tax Treaty Override (Kluwer L. Intl. 2014). 17. Maisto, supra n. 14, at p. 336. Model was only first included in 2003.18 This makes its application questionable with regard to tax treaties con- cluded before 2003. It is known that the OECD argues that the amendments to the Commentaries on the OECD Model are not rele- vant for the interpretation and application of tax treaties concluded prior to their issue when there is a difference in substance.19 On the other hand, where the amendments to the OECD Commentaries are regarded as merely inter- pretive, the OECD argues that such clarifications should be applied to existing tax treaties20,21 to the extent that they reflect the consensus of the OECD member coun- tries regarding the correct interpretation of existing treaty provisions and their proper application to actual cases.22,23 It can sometimes be difficult to identify whether a change to the Commentaries on the OECD Model has instituted a substantial change in the underlying treaty provision, especially when the wording of the OECD Model itself remains unchanged.24 Despite this, when it comes to the compatibility of domestic anti-abuse rules with tax trea- ties, the new position adopted by the OECD is diamet- rically opposed to that which had been adopted by the OECD since the Commentaries on the OECD Model (1977),25 which makes the change made in the Commen- taries on the OECD Model 2003 applicable only to tax treaties entered into after that date.26 In fact, the pre-2003 version of the Commentaries on the OECD Model sug- gested that: it may be appropriate for Contracting States to agree in bilateral negotiations that any relief from tax [provided by a tax treaty] should not apply in certain cases, or to agree that the application of the provisions of domestic laws against tax avoidance should not be affected by the Convention.27 Thus, the pre-2003 version followed the view that domes- tic anti-avoidance rules should be either included or 18. OECD Model Tax Convention on Income and on Capital: Commentary on Article 1 para. 9.2. (28 Jan. 2003), Models IBFD. 19. M. Schmitt, The Relevance of Amendments to the OECD Commentary for the Interpretation of Tax Treaties (Static or Dynamic Approach), in Funda- mental Issues and Practical Problems in Tax Treaty Interpretation p. 121 (M. Schilcher P. Weninger eds., Linde 2008). 20. M. Lang, The Application of the OECD Model Tax Convention to Partner- ships A Critical Analysis of the Report Prepared by the OECD Committee on Fiscal Affairs p. 15 (Linde 2000). 21. K. Provodová, The Relevance of the OECD Report for the Interpretation of Tax Treaties, in Schilcher Weninger, supra n. 19, at p. 151. 22. Seepara.35oftheintroductiontotheOECD Model: Commentaries(2014), according to which: “Needless to say, amendments to the Articles of the Model Convention and to the Commentaries that are a direct result of these amendments are not relevant to the interpretation or application of previously concluded conventions where the provisions of those con- ventions are different in substance from the amended Articles. However, other changes or additions to the Commentaries are normally applicable to the interpretation and application of conventions concluded before their adoption, because they reflect the consensus of the OECD Member countries as to the proper interpretation of existing provisions and their application to specific situations.” 23. Schmitt, supra n. 19, at p. 121. 24. G. Nolte, Report 3. Subsequent Agreements and Subsequent Practice of States Outside of Judicial or Quasi-judicial Proceedings, in Treaties and Subsequent Practice p. 362 (G. Nolte ed., Oxford U. Press 2013). 25. OECD Model Tax Convention on Income and on Capital: Commentary on Article 1 para. 10 (11 Apr. 1977), Models IBFD. 26. Maisto, supra n. 14, at p. 339. 27. OECD, supra n. 25, at para. 10. Exported / Printed on 20 July 2016 by biblio2@ibdt.org.br.
  • 6. 404 BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION JULY 2016 © IBFD Ramon Tomazela Santos confirmed by tax treaty provisions. This approach only changed in 2003, when the OECD put forward the argu- ment that domestic anti-avoidance rules are used to deter- mine the facts that create the tax obligation. Therefore, since these changes in the Commentaries represent a new interpretation, there are good grounds to claim that they cannot be applied to older tax treaties. In any event, due to the lack of consensus on the legal status of the Commen- taryanditsroleintheinterpretationoftaxtreaties,ithasto be acknowledged that tax authorities and national courts may adopt different positions in this regard. A more critical point relies on the fact that the United KingdomsharestheviewoftheOECD,setoutintheCom- mentary on Article 1 of the OECD Model,28 in the sense that tax treaties do not affect the application of domestic anti-abuse rules, as the United Kingdom representatives did not record any observation against this interpretation. As a result, regardless of the legal relevance to be attributed to the Commentaries on the OECD Mode,29 it is clear that the United Kingdom, in interpreting its tax treaties, acts in good faith and in accordance with its unilateral stance, as it did not make any observation on the content of relevant paragraphs of the OECD Commentaries.30 The matter becomes even more complex when it is con- sidered that the UK tax law provides that its GAAR can be applied in a treaty context31 to counter any tax arrange- mentswhenitisreasonabletoconclude,havingtakenallof the facts and circumstances into account, that a taxpayer intended to obtain a tax advantage. In this sense, HMRC has clearly stated that: where there are abusive arrangements which try to exploit par- ticular provisions in a double tax treaty, or the way in which such provisions interact with other provisions of UK tax law, then the GAAR can be applied to counteract the abusive arrangement.32 Although the UK tax law extends its GAAR to a treaty context, this domestic legal provision may also give rise to a debate about whether it constitutes a treaty override,33 as it is a later domestic law that can be applied by HMRC in conflict with treaty provisions. A treaty override, in addi- tion to representing a breach of international law, also gives rise to serious consequences, as it undermines the legal certainty that tax treaties intend to develop. From an international law perspective, article 60 of the Vienna Convention (1969) establishes that: 28. Para. 9.2 OECD Model: Commentary on Article 1 (2014). 29. It is not within the scope of this article to analyse the legal relevance of the OECD Model: Commentaries (2014). In this context, see J.M. Mössner, Klaus Vogel Lecture 2009 Comments, 64 Bull. Intl. Taxn. 1, sec. 2. (2010), Journals IBFD. It is assumed here that the relevance to be attributed to the OECD Model: Commentaries (2014) should be considered on a case- by-case basis. With regard to this, see J. Sasseville, Temporal Aspects of Tax Treaties, in Tax Polymath: A Life in International Taxation Essays in Honour of John F. Avery Jones sec. 3, p. 46 (P. Baker C. Bobbett eds., IBFD 2011), Online Books IBFD. 30. Paras. 9.2, 22.1 and 23 OECD Model: Commentary on Article 1 (2014). 31. J. Schwarz, Schwarz on Tax Treaties, 3rd edn., p. 45 (Wolters Kluwer (UK) Ltd. 2013). 32. HMRC, General Anti Abuse Rule (GAAR) Guidance, para. B.53, available at www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/ file/399270/2__HMRC_GAAR_Guidance_Parts_A-C_with_effect_ from_30_January_2015_AD_V6.pdf. 33. Schwarz, supra n. 31. a material breach of a bilateral treaty by one of the parties entitles the other to invoke the breach as a ground for terminating the treaty or suspending its operation in whole or in part. From economic and practical perspectives, non-resident taxpayers may lose their confidence in the behaviour of the other contracting state, as the tax treatment applying to their investments may suddenly be amended by a uni- lateral and uncoordinated action. Additionally, as tax treaties are primarily concluded by sovereign states, it is clear that the provisions set out in tax treaties must be observed in view of the international public law principle of pacta sunt servanda, as set out in article 26 of the Vienna Convention (1969), which pro- vides that “every treaty in force is binding upon the parties and must be performed in good faith”. This fundamen- tal principle is supplemented by article 27 of the Vienna Convention (1969), according to which “a party may not invoke the provisions of internal law as a justification for its failure to perform a treaty”. Consequently, the contract- ing states embrace a commitment that binds them to not impose taxes on situations in which a tax treaty restricts their taxing rights. Under the international law, there are no possible justifications for a treaty override.34 As a result, even if, under the UK legal system, the doctrine of parlia- mentary sovereignty admits the enactment of domestic laws to override a treaty provision, such a breach of in- ternational law may be invoked by the other contracting state.35 In addition to this infringement, which may be questioned bytheothercontractingstate,itshouldbeemphasizedthat the domestic GAAR enacted by the United Kingdom and extended to the level of tax treaties does not represent a general legitimization of the DPT. The domestic GAAR may be used by HMRC to counter tax advantages arising from tax arrangements that are abusive, but it does not legitimatetheimpositionoftheDPTinanycircumstances, without demonstrating a practice of abusive tax arrange- ments by a taxpayer. It is also important to note that the fictitious character- ization of a PE on the basis of a domestic anti-abuse rule without the support of the wording in the tax treaty may result in double taxation, as the residence state only grants a credit or an exemption in relation to the taxes levied in accordance with the distributive rules of a tax treaty.36 Even if the United Kingdom were to apply its domestic GAAR on the basis that a taxpayer intentionally avoided the characterization of a PE, the other contracting state could hardly adopt the same approach in granting double taxationreliefinatreatycontext.Consequently,thecollec- tion of DPT by the United Kingdom could easily result in the double taxation of business profits, which is precisely what a tax treaty is designed to prevent. 34. P. Ribeiro de Souza, Tax Treaty Override, in Schilcher Weninger, supra n. 19, at p. 255. 35. Schwarz, supra n. 31, at p. 42. 36. M. Helminen, The International Tax Law Concept of Dividend, Series on International Taxation vol. 36, pp. 105-106 (Kluwer L. Intl. 2010). Exported / Printed on 20 July 2016 by biblio2@ibdt.org.br.
  • 7. 405© IBFD BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION JULY 2016 The United Kingdom’ s Diverted Profits Tax and Tax Treaties: An Evaluation As a result, even if the position of the United Kingdom and its domestic GAAR is considered to consistent with the interpretation in the Commentaries on the OECDC Model, the truth is that the collection of the DPT would be contrary to the objective and purpose of a tax treaty. Con- sequently, in a treaty context, the levying of the DPT could only be justified in cases of proven abusive transactions. Another aspect that must be addressed is the fact that various tax treaties concluded by the United Kingdom contain a general anti-abuse clause based on the principal purpose test (PPT). The PPT permits the investigation of the business purpose that guided a taxpayer in undertak- ingcertainactionsortransactions.Theapplicationofsuch a clause to justify the collection of the DPT would depend on a case-by-case analysis. With regard to tax treaties with PPT clauses, tax authorities can only reclassify an action or a transaction carried out by a taxpayer when one of the main purposes of the action or transaction is to prevent, reduce or delay the payment of taxes, without any other economic or business purpose. As a result, only actions or transactions undertaken with the sole or main purpose of avoiding taxes could be recharacterized by tax authorities. Nevertheless, as stated in section 3., the DPT rules do not appear to require an investigation as to whether the sole or primary purpose of a taxpayer is to avoid taxes. In this context, it can be asked whether the DPT is really intended to counter cases in which MNEs artificially avoid the char- acterization of a PE in the United Kingdom without any other business purpose or, conversely, whether it is only a stringent mechanism to tax any sales or services per- formed in the UK domestic market, regardless of the char- acterization of a PE. In the latter case, even if the relevant tax treaty contains a PPT clause, it is possible to challenge the compatibility of the DPT with the equivalent to article 7 of the OECD Model in the tax treaty, given that the tax is levied on the profits obtained by a company resident in the other contracting state without the characterization of a PE in the United Kingdom. Finally, it should be noted that, in the UK tax system, tax treaties only have effect insofar as domestic law so pro- vides. It may be debatable whether the Taxation (Inter- national and Other Provisions) Act (TIOPA) 2010 gives effect to tax treaties in relation to DPT, as this states that: [d]ouble taxation arrangements have effect in relation to income tax and corporation tax so far as the arrangements provide ... (b) for taxing income of non-UK resident persons that arises from sources in the United Kingdom.37 Although the DPT cannot be considered to be income tax or corporation tax under the UK domestic tax law, it is 37. UK: Taxation (International and Other Provisions) Act (TIOPA) sec. 6(2) (b) 2010. undeniable that a tax treaty validly concluded is binding from an international law perspective. For this reason, the other contracting state may challenge the breach of the provisions of a tax treaty by the United Kingdom given the introduction of the DPT. This may result in a tax treaty being terminated or suspended under international law. 5. Conclusions The equivalent of article 2(4) of the OECD Model in the tax treaties concluded by the United Kingdom encompasses any identical or substantially similar taxes that are imposed after the date of the signature of a tax treaty. As the tax base of the DPT corresponds to the profits that would have been attributed to a PE, it can be considered to be a tax levied on elements of income. As taxpayers have the right to choose the actions and transactions that they put into effect, the simple fact that the business model adopted falls within the definition of a PE does not authorize the collection of a similar tax, in contradiction to the international obligations assumed in a tax treaty. Consequently, the levying of the DPT should be restricted to cases where HMRC can clearly demonstrate the artificiality of the legal structure used by a taxpayer. In addition, if the structure used by the taxpayer has an unintended result in light of the traditional definition of a PE, the United Kingdom should renegotiate its tax treaties to amend the definition of a PE, instead of imposing a new tax. Although UK tax law provides that its GAAR can be applied in a treaty context, such a breach of international law through a treaty override may be invoked by the other contracting state to terminate the tax treaty. In addition, the fact that the UK domestic GAAR may be used by HMRC to counter artificial tax arrangements does not legitimate the levying of the DPT in any circumstances, without proof of abuse. Finally, despite the fact that, within the UK legal system, tax treaties only have effect insofar as the domestic law so provides, it is undeniable that a tax treaty validly concluded is binding from an international law perspective. Consequently, the other contracting state may challenge the breach of the tax treaty by the United Kingdom arising as a result of the introduction of the DPT. Exported / Printed on 20 July 2016 by biblio2@ibdt.org.br.