SlideShare uma empresa Scribd logo
1 de 27
Everything you need to know
about isocosts and isoquants to
prove HO, Stolper-Samuelson,
  and Rybczynski theorems.
The behavior of the firm
• Firms are assumed to attempt to maximize profits.
• First, the firm must identify the profit maximizing
  level of output – the quantity where marginal
  revenue equals marginal cost.
• Next, the firm must minimize the cost of producing
  that level of output.
• It must choose the appropriate technology and
  apply it correctly. As a part of this, it must
  combine resources according to the least-cost
  recipe.


                                                        2
Learning Objectives
• Calculate and graph a firm’s isocost line
• Work out how the isocost line changes when
  resource prices or total cost change
• Make a map of production recipes (technology)
  using isoquants
• Explain the choices that firms make
• Prove three theorems relating to the HO model


                                                  3
A Cost Function: Two Resources
• Assume that there are two resources, Labor (L)
  and Capital (K).
• The money payments to these resources are
  Wages (W) and Rent (R). An isocost line is similar
  to the budget line. It’s a set of points with the
  same cost, C. Let’s plot K on the y axis and L on
  the x axis.
    WL + RK = C; solve for K by first subtracting WL from both
    sides.
    RK = C - WL; next divide both sides by R.
    K = C/R – (W/R)L; note that C/R is the y intercept and W/R is
    the slope.
                                                                    5
An isocost line

    K (machines rented)




                          Absolute value of slope equals
    C/R                   The relative price of Labor, W/R.




                                C/W Labor hours used in
                                    production
                                                              6
A Numerical Example
      Bundles of:     Labor                  Machine rental
      with C = $30 ($6 per labor hour)       ($3 per machine hour)

              a               0                      10
              b               1                       8
              c               2                       6
              d               3                       4
              e               4                       2
              f               5                       0


Points a through f lie on the isocost line for C = $30/hour.

                                                                     7
The Isocost Line
Capital, K (machines rented)


                                    a
                               10
                                            b
                                8
                                                c
                                6
                                                        d
                                4
                                                                e
                                2
                                                                        f
                                0       1   2       3       4       5       6   7    8   9   10
                                                                            Labor, L (worker-hours employed)
                                                                                                               8
The Isocost Line
• Wage-rental ratio
  – With K on the y axis and L on the x axis, the slope
    of any isocost line equals W/R, the wage-rental
    ratio. It is also the relative price of labor.

• The y-intercept shows the number of units of K
  that could be rented for $C.

• The x-intercept shows the number of units of L
  that could be hired for $C.

                                                      11
Changes in One Resource Price
 Capital, K (machines rented)

                                                     Cost = $30; R = $3/machine
                                     a               The money wage, W = ...
                                10

                                 8

                                 6                                                      A Change
                                                                                        in W
                                 4
                                                             …$6
                                 2
                                     …$10
                                                     h           f
                                 0       1   2   3       4   5       6   7    8   9   10
                                                                         Labor, L (worker-hours employed)
                                                                                                            12
Changes in Cost
Capital, K (machines rented)



                               10
                                                              A Change
                                8
                                                              in Cost; every point
                                6 g                           between g and h costs $18.

                                4

                                2                              W = $6; R = $3;C = $30

                                                  h
                                0     1   2   3       4   5   6    7   8    9    10
                                                                  Labor, L (worker-hours employed)
                                                                                                     14
Each point on a given
An Isoquant                                                          isoquant represents different
                                                                     recipes for producing the
                                                                     same level of output.
Capital, K (machines rented)
                               12

                               10

                                8
                                        i
                                6
                                                                Quantity of Soybeans = 1 (kg./hour)
                                4

                                2
                                                j
                                0   1       2       3   4   5    6    7    8     9    10
                                                                      Labor, L (worker-hours employed)
                                                                                                         17
Different isoquants
                                 An Isoquant Map                          represents different levels of
                                                                          output.
                               9 10
Capital, K (machines rented)




                                                          m
                               8




                                                                            Quantity of Soybeans = 2 (kg./hour)
                               7
                               6
                               5
                               4




                                                                      k
                               3




                                                      j
                               2




                                                                             Quantity of Soybeans = 1 (kg./hour)
                               1
                               0




                                      0   1   2   3   4   5   6   7   8   9 10
                                                                           Labor, L (worker-hours employed) 18
Choose the recipe where the
Cost Minimization                                                     desired isoquant is tangent to
                                                                      the lowest isocost.
   Capital, K (machines rented)
                                  12
                                       a
                                  10

                                   8
                                                               C = $36
                                   6
                                                                W = $6; R = $3;C = $30
                                   4           equ.
                                   2
                                       C = $18

                                   0       1   2   3   4   5      6      7    8   9   10
                                                                         Labor, L (worker-hours employed)
                                                                                                            21
Conclusion: Buy resources such
that the last dollar spent on K adds
the same amount to output as the
last dollar spent on L.
• The |slope| of the isocost line = W/R.
• The |slope| of the isoquant = MPL/MPK
  – This will be demonstrated on the board.



                                              22
Proof of the HO theorem (price definition).




                                              24
Preparing to Prove the Heckscher-Ohlin theorem.
  In our example in class and the handouts, we demonstrated the theorem
  by assuming that Country A was relatively capital abundant, giving it
  comparative advantage in the capital-intensive good, S. Before we prove
  the theorem, study the figure above. Two isoquants are shown. Each
  represents all the technically efficient combinations of resources that
  could be used to produce one unit of a particular product. The isoquant
  for S lies closer to the K axis because S is the K-intensive good. The
  isoquant for T lies closer to the L axis because T is the L-intensive good.
  Only one isoquant is drawn for each good. However, our assumption of
  constant returns to scale means that the isoquant for two units of a good
  will require twice as much of each input. Thus the map of isoquants is
  regularly spaced. If we can prove a theorem for one output level, then it
  will be valid for all output levels. The assumption of constant returns to
  scale (and no fixed costs) also implies that average cost and marginal
  cost are constant and equal to each other for all levels of production.
  Note also that the assumption that both countries have access to the
  same set of technologies means that their isoquant maps are identical.



                                                                                25
Proof of the Heckscher-Ohlin theorem.
To prove the theorem from the price definition of factor abundance, we
must show that a higher wage-rental ratio in A implies that B will have a
lower autarkic relative price of T (and that A will have a lower autarkic
relative price of S). Suppose that the autarkic relative price of S (PS/PT)
in A equals 1. Then the line segment GH is the pre-trade isocost line
facing A’s firms. Why? Given PS = PT and that P = MC = AC, the cost of
producing one unit of S must equal the cost of producing one unit of T.
Point G represents the following ratios:

(MCSA = PSA = MCTA = PTA)/RA.

By the same reasoning, point H represents the following ratios:

(MCSA = PSA = MCTA = PTA)/WA .

Thus the slope of the line connecting points G and H equals the pre-
trade wage-rental ratio in A, WA/RA.


                                                                              26
Proof of the Heckscher-Ohlin theorem (continued)
  Now consider country B, which represents the labor-abundant country.
  Country B’s greater relative supply of labor means that it will have a
  lower autarkic wage-rental ratio. Two separate, parallel isocost lines are
  required to represent B’s optimal input choices for one unit of each good.
   These choices are represented by points X and Y. Note that the isocost
  line CX lies above the isocost line EY. Thus, the marginal cost of
  producing one unit of S in B is greater than the marginal cost of
  producing one unit of T in B. That is, MCSB > MCTB. Since price equals
  marginal cost, it follows that PSB > PTB. This is exactly what we were
  seeking to prove. That is, if the relative price of S in A equals one, then
  the relative price of S in B is greater than one. Thus A has a comparative
  advantage in S and B has a comparative advantage in T.




                                                                                27
Proof of the Stolper-Samuelson theorem.
                       Home is Labor abundant, T is
                       Labor intensive. The initial
                       isocost line is tangent to the S
                       and T isoquants at F and D. $1
                       worth of each good costs $1 to
                       produce.
                       With trade PT/PS rises.
                       (Assume only PT changes.)
                       Note that W/R must rise
                       proportionately more.




                                                          28
Proof of the Stolper-Samuelson theorem.
When PT rises, Home will sell fewer units of T for $1. The new isoquant
is T’. The new isocost line is tangent to the S isoquant at F’ and tangent
to the T’ isoquant at D’.


R’ < R. The money return to capital falls. PS is unchanged, but PT has
risen. Thus the real return to capital falls.


W’ > W. The money wage rises. Workers can now buy more S, as its
price is unchanged. But can they buy more T?

The increase in the wage rate is shown by the proportion (1/W)/(1/W’).
This is greater than the proportionate increase in the price of T, which is
the ratio of line segment 0D to 0R, 0D / 0R. The real wage in terms of T
has also risen. Thus the real return to Labor rises.




                                                                              29
Proof of the Stolper-Samuelson theorem (more words)

 The Stolper-Samuelson theorem states that the factor that is used
 intensively in a product whose relative price has risen gains, while the
 other factor loses. In the context of the HO model, this means that the
 abundant factor gains from trade while the scarce factor loses. Consider
 the figure.
 As before, we illustrate two isoquants representing $1 of output of S and
 T, respectively. Given the initial prices, wage and rental rates, the
 optimal combination of inputs are shown by points F and D.
 When trade is opened, the country with comparative advantage in good
 T will experience an increase in the relative price of T. At a higher price
 for T, $1 worth of this product would lie on a lower isoquant (remember
 that isoquants refer to physical units). Thus the T=$1 isoquant would
 become the isoquant labeled T’. If some of both goods are still to be
 produced, the $1 isocost line must rotate to maintain tangency with the
 two isoquants S and T’. How can this be accomplished? Wages and
 rents must change. The new isocost line has intercepts $1/R’ and $1/W’.
 Since the numerators of these fractions are the same as before, we can
 deduce what has happened to rents and wages by simply comparing 1/R
  with 1/R’ and 1/W with 1/W’. (continued on next slide)
                                                                               30
Proof of the Stolper-Samuelson theorem (continued)
    In the first case, the fraction has risen. This could occur only if R’ < R,
    that is , if rents have fallen. On the other hand, a comparison of
    horizontal intercepts shows that W has risen. These changes in W and R
    are nominal changes. What has happened to the purchasing power of
    capitalists and laborers? For capitalists, the answer is straightforward.
    We have assumed that the price of S has stayed fixed while the price of
    T has risen. A fall in R, therefore, means that capitalists have lost
    purchasing power in terms of either product – they are definitely worse
    off when the price of the labor-intensive good T rises relative to the price
    of the capital-intensive good S. What about labor? The rise in W
    definitely means that labor can afford to purchase more S, because its
    price has been assumed to remain constant. However, the price of T has
    risen. Can labor buy more or less of this product? The answer is more.
    How do we know? Graphically, the increase in wages can be found by
    comparing the proportions (1/W)/(1/W’). This increase is greater than the
    proportionate increase in the price of T, which can be found by the ratio
    of the line segments 0D/0R. (Given CRS, the isoquants are evenly
    spaced.) This proves the theorem.


                                                                                   31
Notes on Stolper Samuelson
Why does the ratio 0D/OR represent the proportionate
increase in the price of T? This is a bit hard to see at first.
Suppose that R and W (and C) rose by the same proportion as
PT. Then the $1 isocost line would shift in (parallel) to be
tangent at R. This lower quantity of T costs $1 to produce,
and would sell for $1. Since price equals marginal cost equals
average cost, the increase in cost at D (which now costs more
than $1) will equal the increase in price. Thus 0D/0R
represents the proportionate increase in price.




                                                                  32
A more formal explanation:
Why does the ratio 0D/OR represent the proportionate
increase in the price of T?
We know that PTT = P’TT’ (= $1). Divide both sides by PTT’ to
get :          T/T’ = P’T/ PT
0D = T and 0R = T’. T
Thus 0D/0R = P’T/ PT, the proportionate increase in price.

Looking at the graph reveals that W’/W > 0D/OR.

Therefore, W’/W > P’T/ PT.

Thus workers’ real wage has risen in terms of both T and S
because the money wage has increased by more than the price
of either good.                                             33
Proof of the Rybczynski theorem




                                  34
Proof of the Rybczynski theorem
The Rybczynski theorem states that if a country experiences an increase
in its endowment of any one factor (say, labor), then, holding all other
things constant (including factor and product prices), the output of the
good that uses the factor intensively will rise, and the output of the other
good will fall. To prove this theorem, refer to the isoquant map shown in
the figure. Each of the two isoquants shown represents the output of $1
worth of one good, S or T. Suppose that the relative price of S is equal to
1. As discussed in the proof of the HO theorem, this must imply that
there is an isocost line that is just tangent to the two isoquants, just as
drawn. Furthermore, we know that the vertical and horizontal intercepts
of this isocost line must equal $1/R and $1/W, respectively. The
tangency points F and D determine the optimal input combinations to
produce $1 of S output and $1 of T output. If wages and rental rates are
held fixed, the assumptions of constant returns to scale guarantees that
the slope of the rays from the origin passing through point F and D
determines the optimal capital/labor ratios for the two industries, given
those factor prices.
 (continued on next slide)


                                                                               35
Proof of the Rybczynski theorem (continued)
How does the economy divide its output between the two products? This
depends upon the overall supply of available factors of production.
Suppose that the economy is initially endowed with a set of factors
defined by point E. To find the optimal production of S and T, complete
the parallelogram from point E to the two rays emanating from the origin.
This defines points G and H on the two rays. These points represent
optimal production levels of S and T, given the prices prevailing in the
economy. How do we know that this is true? First, we know that output
must occur on the rays. Second, we want to use all available resources.
If we add the factor combination represented by the line 0G to the point
H, we reach the total endowment level E. Similarly, if we add 0H to G, we
also reach point E.
Now we are in position to prove the theorem. Suppose that the country’s
endowment of labor rises, but capital and prices do not change. This
pulls the country’s endowment point horizontally away form E to , say, E’.
By completing the parallelogram with points E’ and 0 at the corners, we
see that the optimal production levels of S and T have changed from
their old levels. In particular, the output of S has fallen (to G’), while that
of T has risen (to H’). This proves the theorem.
                                                                                  36

Mais conteúdo relacionado

Mais procurados

Mais procurados (20)

Profit maximization
Profit maximizationProfit maximization
Profit maximization
 
Bba ii cost and management accounting u 2.1 labour cost
Bba ii cost and management accounting u 2.1 labour costBba ii cost and management accounting u 2.1 labour cost
Bba ii cost and management accounting u 2.1 labour cost
 
Class 3 isocosts & isoquants
Class 3 isocosts & isoquantsClass 3 isocosts & isoquants
Class 3 isocosts & isoquants
 
Cost theory
Cost theoryCost theory
Cost theory
 
theory of production and cost
theory of production and costtheory of production and cost
theory of production and cost
 
Costs functions
Costs functionsCosts functions
Costs functions
 
Teori biaya-produksi
Teori biaya-produksiTeori biaya-produksi
Teori biaya-produksi
 
Isocost
IsocostIsocost
Isocost
 
Cost Concept
Cost ConceptCost Concept
Cost Concept
 
Theory of cost
Theory of costTheory of cost
Theory of cost
 
ISOCOST & LEAST COST COMBINATION-CS.FINAL YEAR
ISOCOST & LEAST COST COMBINATION-CS.FINAL YEARISOCOST & LEAST COST COMBINATION-CS.FINAL YEAR
ISOCOST & LEAST COST COMBINATION-CS.FINAL YEAR
 
Pasar Monopsoni - Teori Ekonomi Mikro
Pasar Monopsoni - Teori Ekonomi MikroPasar Monopsoni - Teori Ekonomi Mikro
Pasar Monopsoni - Teori Ekonomi Mikro
 
Theory of Production
Theory of ProductionTheory of Production
Theory of Production
 
1. Matematika ekonomi Mr Imam awaludin
1. Matematika ekonomi Mr Imam awaludin1. Matematika ekonomi Mr Imam awaludin
1. Matematika ekonomi Mr Imam awaludin
 
Ppt on Cost accounting and its classifications
Ppt on Cost accounting and its classifications Ppt on Cost accounting and its classifications
Ppt on Cost accounting and its classifications
 
Theory of cost
Theory of costTheory of cost
Theory of cost
 
Cost Minimization
Cost Minimization Cost Minimization
Cost Minimization
 
CONCEPT OF COST
CONCEPT OF COSTCONCEPT OF COST
CONCEPT OF COST
 
Customs duty ppt
Customs duty ppt Customs duty ppt
Customs duty ppt
 
Import procedure
Import procedureImport procedure
Import procedure
 

Destaque

Isoquants and returns to scale
Isoquants and returns to scaleIsoquants and returns to scale
Isoquants and returns to scaleKartikeya Shukla
 
Towards a Theory of Consumption - Jean Baudrillard
Towards a Theory of Consumption - Jean BaudrillardTowards a Theory of Consumption - Jean Baudrillard
Towards a Theory of Consumption - Jean BaudrillardBurak Taşdizen
 
Isoquants and its properties
Isoquants and its propertiesIsoquants and its properties
Isoquants and its propertiesAwesh Bhornya
 
Agri 2312 chapter 7 economics of input and product substitution
Agri 2312 chapter 7 economics of input and product substitutionAgri 2312 chapter 7 economics of input and product substitution
Agri 2312 chapter 7 economics of input and product substitutionRita Conley
 
Presentation on dawco
Presentation on dawcoPresentation on dawco
Presentation on dawcoAnees Jamro
 
Thelaw of returns to scale
Thelaw of returns to scaleThelaw of returns to scale
Thelaw of returns to scaleHamza Ali
 
8 productionpart2
8 productionpart28 productionpart2
8 productionpart2gannibhai
 
Returns to scale and its implications
Returns to scale and its implicationsReturns to scale and its implications
Returns to scale and its implicationsAwesh Bhornya
 
Damco Corporate Presentation
Damco Corporate PresentationDamco Corporate Presentation
Damco Corporate Presentationamargupta27
 
Damco Corporate Presentation
Damco Corporate PresentationDamco Corporate Presentation
Damco Corporate Presentationamargupta27
 
Notes on decisions making
Notes on decisions makingNotes on decisions making
Notes on decisions makingOsmawati Osman
 
indifference_curve
indifference_curveindifference_curve
indifference_curveEkta Doger
 
Laws Of Return in Economics
Laws Of Return in EconomicsLaws Of Return in Economics
Laws Of Return in EconomicsRahat Inayat Ali
 
Law of returns to scale
Law of returns to scaleLaw of returns to scale
Law of returns to scaleNamita Sharma
 

Destaque (20)

Isoquants
IsoquantsIsoquants
Isoquants
 
Isoquant
IsoquantIsoquant
Isoquant
 
Isoquants
IsoquantsIsoquants
Isoquants
 
Isoquants and returns to scale
Isoquants and returns to scaleIsoquants and returns to scale
Isoquants and returns to scale
 
Production 2
Production 2Production 2
Production 2
 
Towards a Theory of Consumption - Jean Baudrillard
Towards a Theory of Consumption - Jean BaudrillardTowards a Theory of Consumption - Jean Baudrillard
Towards a Theory of Consumption - Jean Baudrillard
 
Isocost.2
Isocost.2Isocost.2
Isocost.2
 
Isoquants and its properties
Isoquants and its propertiesIsoquants and its properties
Isoquants and its properties
 
DAMCO Exp
DAMCO ExpDAMCO Exp
DAMCO Exp
 
Agri 2312 chapter 7 economics of input and product substitution
Agri 2312 chapter 7 economics of input and product substitutionAgri 2312 chapter 7 economics of input and product substitution
Agri 2312 chapter 7 economics of input and product substitution
 
Presentation on dawco
Presentation on dawcoPresentation on dawco
Presentation on dawco
 
Thelaw of returns to scale
Thelaw of returns to scaleThelaw of returns to scale
Thelaw of returns to scale
 
8 productionpart2
8 productionpart28 productionpart2
8 productionpart2
 
Returns to scale and its implications
Returns to scale and its implicationsReturns to scale and its implications
Returns to scale and its implications
 
Damco Corporate Presentation
Damco Corporate PresentationDamco Corporate Presentation
Damco Corporate Presentation
 
Damco Corporate Presentation
Damco Corporate PresentationDamco Corporate Presentation
Damco Corporate Presentation
 
Notes on decisions making
Notes on decisions makingNotes on decisions making
Notes on decisions making
 
indifference_curve
indifference_curveindifference_curve
indifference_curve
 
Laws Of Return in Economics
Laws Of Return in EconomicsLaws Of Return in Economics
Laws Of Return in Economics
 
Law of returns to scale
Law of returns to scaleLaw of returns to scale
Law of returns to scale
 

Semelhante a Isocosts isoquants and proofs

Semelhante a Isocosts isoquants and proofs (11)

Rambo
RamboRambo
Rambo
 
7th Semester Mechanical Engineering (June/July-2015) Question Papers
7th Semester Mechanical Engineering  (June/July-2015) Question Papers7th Semester Mechanical Engineering  (June/July-2015) Question Papers
7th Semester Mechanical Engineering (June/July-2015) Question Papers
 
7th Semester Mechanical Engineering (Dec-2015; Jan-2016) Question Papers
7th Semester Mechanical Engineering (Dec-2015; Jan-2016) Question Papers7th Semester Mechanical Engineering (Dec-2015; Jan-2016) Question Papers
7th Semester Mechanical Engineering (Dec-2015; Jan-2016) Question Papers
 
3.1 Production (Week 8) Economics chapter 3
3.1 Production (Week 8) Economics chapter 33.1 Production (Week 8) Economics chapter 3
3.1 Production (Week 8) Economics chapter 3
 
Slope rate-change-tables worksheet
Slope rate-change-tables worksheetSlope rate-change-tables worksheet
Slope rate-change-tables worksheet
 
EC4004 Lecture 10: Costs
EC4004 Lecture 10: CostsEC4004 Lecture 10: Costs
EC4004 Lecture 10: Costs
 
05210202 Fluid Mechanics And Hydraulic Machinery
05210202 Fluid Mechanics  And  Hydraulic Machinery05210202 Fluid Mechanics  And  Hydraulic Machinery
05210202 Fluid Mechanics And Hydraulic Machinery
 
03 Chemical Engineering Plant Design And Economics
03 Chemical Engineering Plant Design And Economics03 Chemical Engineering Plant Design And Economics
03 Chemical Engineering Plant Design And Economics
 
1.10 Variations
1.10 Variations1.10 Variations
1.10 Variations
 
4th Semester MBA (June-2014) Question Papers
4th Semester MBA (June-2014) Question Papers4th Semester MBA (June-2014) Question Papers
4th Semester MBA (June-2014) Question Papers
 
Expansion path
Expansion pathExpansion path
Expansion path
 

Isocosts isoquants and proofs

  • 1. Everything you need to know about isocosts and isoquants to prove HO, Stolper-Samuelson, and Rybczynski theorems.
  • 2. The behavior of the firm • Firms are assumed to attempt to maximize profits. • First, the firm must identify the profit maximizing level of output – the quantity where marginal revenue equals marginal cost. • Next, the firm must minimize the cost of producing that level of output. • It must choose the appropriate technology and apply it correctly. As a part of this, it must combine resources according to the least-cost recipe. 2
  • 3. Learning Objectives • Calculate and graph a firm’s isocost line • Work out how the isocost line changes when resource prices or total cost change • Make a map of production recipes (technology) using isoquants • Explain the choices that firms make • Prove three theorems relating to the HO model 3
  • 4. A Cost Function: Two Resources • Assume that there are two resources, Labor (L) and Capital (K). • The money payments to these resources are Wages (W) and Rent (R). An isocost line is similar to the budget line. It’s a set of points with the same cost, C. Let’s plot K on the y axis and L on the x axis. WL + RK = C; solve for K by first subtracting WL from both sides. RK = C - WL; next divide both sides by R. K = C/R – (W/R)L; note that C/R is the y intercept and W/R is the slope. 5
  • 5. An isocost line K (machines rented) Absolute value of slope equals C/R The relative price of Labor, W/R. C/W Labor hours used in production 6
  • 6. A Numerical Example Bundles of: Labor Machine rental with C = $30 ($6 per labor hour) ($3 per machine hour) a 0 10 b 1 8 c 2 6 d 3 4 e 4 2 f 5 0 Points a through f lie on the isocost line for C = $30/hour. 7
  • 7. The Isocost Line Capital, K (machines rented) a 10 b 8 c 6 d 4 e 2 f 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Labor, L (worker-hours employed) 8
  • 8. The Isocost Line • Wage-rental ratio – With K on the y axis and L on the x axis, the slope of any isocost line equals W/R, the wage-rental ratio. It is also the relative price of labor. • The y-intercept shows the number of units of K that could be rented for $C. • The x-intercept shows the number of units of L that could be hired for $C. 11
  • 9. Changes in One Resource Price Capital, K (machines rented) Cost = $30; R = $3/machine a The money wage, W = ... 10 8 6 A Change in W 4 …$6 2 …$10 h f 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Labor, L (worker-hours employed) 12
  • 10. Changes in Cost Capital, K (machines rented) 10 A Change 8 in Cost; every point 6 g between g and h costs $18. 4 2 W = $6; R = $3;C = $30 h 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Labor, L (worker-hours employed) 14
  • 11. Each point on a given An Isoquant isoquant represents different recipes for producing the same level of output. Capital, K (machines rented) 12 10 8 i 6 Quantity of Soybeans = 1 (kg./hour) 4 2 j 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Labor, L (worker-hours employed) 17
  • 12. Different isoquants An Isoquant Map represents different levels of output. 9 10 Capital, K (machines rented) m 8 Quantity of Soybeans = 2 (kg./hour) 7 6 5 4 k 3 j 2 Quantity of Soybeans = 1 (kg./hour) 1 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Labor, L (worker-hours employed) 18
  • 13. Choose the recipe where the Cost Minimization desired isoquant is tangent to the lowest isocost. Capital, K (machines rented) 12 a 10 8 C = $36 6 W = $6; R = $3;C = $30 4 equ. 2 C = $18 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Labor, L (worker-hours employed) 21
  • 14. Conclusion: Buy resources such that the last dollar spent on K adds the same amount to output as the last dollar spent on L. • The |slope| of the isocost line = W/R. • The |slope| of the isoquant = MPL/MPK – This will be demonstrated on the board. 22
  • 15. Proof of the HO theorem (price definition). 24
  • 16. Preparing to Prove the Heckscher-Ohlin theorem. In our example in class and the handouts, we demonstrated the theorem by assuming that Country A was relatively capital abundant, giving it comparative advantage in the capital-intensive good, S. Before we prove the theorem, study the figure above. Two isoquants are shown. Each represents all the technically efficient combinations of resources that could be used to produce one unit of a particular product. The isoquant for S lies closer to the K axis because S is the K-intensive good. The isoquant for T lies closer to the L axis because T is the L-intensive good. Only one isoquant is drawn for each good. However, our assumption of constant returns to scale means that the isoquant for two units of a good will require twice as much of each input. Thus the map of isoquants is regularly spaced. If we can prove a theorem for one output level, then it will be valid for all output levels. The assumption of constant returns to scale (and no fixed costs) also implies that average cost and marginal cost are constant and equal to each other for all levels of production. Note also that the assumption that both countries have access to the same set of technologies means that their isoquant maps are identical. 25
  • 17. Proof of the Heckscher-Ohlin theorem. To prove the theorem from the price definition of factor abundance, we must show that a higher wage-rental ratio in A implies that B will have a lower autarkic relative price of T (and that A will have a lower autarkic relative price of S). Suppose that the autarkic relative price of S (PS/PT) in A equals 1. Then the line segment GH is the pre-trade isocost line facing A’s firms. Why? Given PS = PT and that P = MC = AC, the cost of producing one unit of S must equal the cost of producing one unit of T. Point G represents the following ratios: (MCSA = PSA = MCTA = PTA)/RA. By the same reasoning, point H represents the following ratios: (MCSA = PSA = MCTA = PTA)/WA . Thus the slope of the line connecting points G and H equals the pre- trade wage-rental ratio in A, WA/RA. 26
  • 18. Proof of the Heckscher-Ohlin theorem (continued) Now consider country B, which represents the labor-abundant country. Country B’s greater relative supply of labor means that it will have a lower autarkic wage-rental ratio. Two separate, parallel isocost lines are required to represent B’s optimal input choices for one unit of each good. These choices are represented by points X and Y. Note that the isocost line CX lies above the isocost line EY. Thus, the marginal cost of producing one unit of S in B is greater than the marginal cost of producing one unit of T in B. That is, MCSB > MCTB. Since price equals marginal cost, it follows that PSB > PTB. This is exactly what we were seeking to prove. That is, if the relative price of S in A equals one, then the relative price of S in B is greater than one. Thus A has a comparative advantage in S and B has a comparative advantage in T. 27
  • 19. Proof of the Stolper-Samuelson theorem. Home is Labor abundant, T is Labor intensive. The initial isocost line is tangent to the S and T isoquants at F and D. $1 worth of each good costs $1 to produce. With trade PT/PS rises. (Assume only PT changes.) Note that W/R must rise proportionately more. 28
  • 20. Proof of the Stolper-Samuelson theorem. When PT rises, Home will sell fewer units of T for $1. The new isoquant is T’. The new isocost line is tangent to the S isoquant at F’ and tangent to the T’ isoquant at D’. R’ < R. The money return to capital falls. PS is unchanged, but PT has risen. Thus the real return to capital falls. W’ > W. The money wage rises. Workers can now buy more S, as its price is unchanged. But can they buy more T? The increase in the wage rate is shown by the proportion (1/W)/(1/W’). This is greater than the proportionate increase in the price of T, which is the ratio of line segment 0D to 0R, 0D / 0R. The real wage in terms of T has also risen. Thus the real return to Labor rises. 29
  • 21. Proof of the Stolper-Samuelson theorem (more words) The Stolper-Samuelson theorem states that the factor that is used intensively in a product whose relative price has risen gains, while the other factor loses. In the context of the HO model, this means that the abundant factor gains from trade while the scarce factor loses. Consider the figure. As before, we illustrate two isoquants representing $1 of output of S and T, respectively. Given the initial prices, wage and rental rates, the optimal combination of inputs are shown by points F and D. When trade is opened, the country with comparative advantage in good T will experience an increase in the relative price of T. At a higher price for T, $1 worth of this product would lie on a lower isoquant (remember that isoquants refer to physical units). Thus the T=$1 isoquant would become the isoquant labeled T’. If some of both goods are still to be produced, the $1 isocost line must rotate to maintain tangency with the two isoquants S and T’. How can this be accomplished? Wages and rents must change. The new isocost line has intercepts $1/R’ and $1/W’. Since the numerators of these fractions are the same as before, we can deduce what has happened to rents and wages by simply comparing 1/R with 1/R’ and 1/W with 1/W’. (continued on next slide) 30
  • 22. Proof of the Stolper-Samuelson theorem (continued) In the first case, the fraction has risen. This could occur only if R’ < R, that is , if rents have fallen. On the other hand, a comparison of horizontal intercepts shows that W has risen. These changes in W and R are nominal changes. What has happened to the purchasing power of capitalists and laborers? For capitalists, the answer is straightforward. We have assumed that the price of S has stayed fixed while the price of T has risen. A fall in R, therefore, means that capitalists have lost purchasing power in terms of either product – they are definitely worse off when the price of the labor-intensive good T rises relative to the price of the capital-intensive good S. What about labor? The rise in W definitely means that labor can afford to purchase more S, because its price has been assumed to remain constant. However, the price of T has risen. Can labor buy more or less of this product? The answer is more. How do we know? Graphically, the increase in wages can be found by comparing the proportions (1/W)/(1/W’). This increase is greater than the proportionate increase in the price of T, which can be found by the ratio of the line segments 0D/0R. (Given CRS, the isoquants are evenly spaced.) This proves the theorem. 31
  • 23. Notes on Stolper Samuelson Why does the ratio 0D/OR represent the proportionate increase in the price of T? This is a bit hard to see at first. Suppose that R and W (and C) rose by the same proportion as PT. Then the $1 isocost line would shift in (parallel) to be tangent at R. This lower quantity of T costs $1 to produce, and would sell for $1. Since price equals marginal cost equals average cost, the increase in cost at D (which now costs more than $1) will equal the increase in price. Thus 0D/0R represents the proportionate increase in price. 32
  • 24. A more formal explanation: Why does the ratio 0D/OR represent the proportionate increase in the price of T? We know that PTT = P’TT’ (= $1). Divide both sides by PTT’ to get : T/T’ = P’T/ PT 0D = T and 0R = T’. T Thus 0D/0R = P’T/ PT, the proportionate increase in price. Looking at the graph reveals that W’/W > 0D/OR. Therefore, W’/W > P’T/ PT. Thus workers’ real wage has risen in terms of both T and S because the money wage has increased by more than the price of either good. 33
  • 25. Proof of the Rybczynski theorem 34
  • 26. Proof of the Rybczynski theorem The Rybczynski theorem states that if a country experiences an increase in its endowment of any one factor (say, labor), then, holding all other things constant (including factor and product prices), the output of the good that uses the factor intensively will rise, and the output of the other good will fall. To prove this theorem, refer to the isoquant map shown in the figure. Each of the two isoquants shown represents the output of $1 worth of one good, S or T. Suppose that the relative price of S is equal to 1. As discussed in the proof of the HO theorem, this must imply that there is an isocost line that is just tangent to the two isoquants, just as drawn. Furthermore, we know that the vertical and horizontal intercepts of this isocost line must equal $1/R and $1/W, respectively. The tangency points F and D determine the optimal input combinations to produce $1 of S output and $1 of T output. If wages and rental rates are held fixed, the assumptions of constant returns to scale guarantees that the slope of the rays from the origin passing through point F and D determines the optimal capital/labor ratios for the two industries, given those factor prices. (continued on next slide) 35
  • 27. Proof of the Rybczynski theorem (continued) How does the economy divide its output between the two products? This depends upon the overall supply of available factors of production. Suppose that the economy is initially endowed with a set of factors defined by point E. To find the optimal production of S and T, complete the parallelogram from point E to the two rays emanating from the origin. This defines points G and H on the two rays. These points represent optimal production levels of S and T, given the prices prevailing in the economy. How do we know that this is true? First, we know that output must occur on the rays. Second, we want to use all available resources. If we add the factor combination represented by the line 0G to the point H, we reach the total endowment level E. Similarly, if we add 0H to G, we also reach point E. Now we are in position to prove the theorem. Suppose that the country’s endowment of labor rises, but capital and prices do not change. This pulls the country’s endowment point horizontally away form E to , say, E’. By completing the parallelogram with points E’ and 0 at the corners, we see that the optimal production levels of S and T have changed from their old levels. In particular, the output of S has fallen (to G’), while that of T has risen (to H’). This proves the theorem. 36

Notas do Editor

  1. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model
  2. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model
  3. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model
  4. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model
  5. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model
  6. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model
  7. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model Instructor Notes: 1) The rows of the table list combinations of labor and capital costing $30, rent is $3 per machine hour, and the wage is $6 per hour. 2) For example, row shows us that how much K could be hired for $30: 10 machine hours but no labor.
  8. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model
  9. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model Instructor Points: 1) The isocost line is the continuous line af . 2) To calculate the equation, start with expenditure equal to C: $3K + $6L = $30 Divide by $3 to obtain K + 2L= 10 Subtract 2L from both sides to obtain K = 10 – 2L
  10. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model
  11. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model
  12. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model
  13. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model
  14. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model Instructor Notes: 1) Lisa’s income falls from $30 to $15 while the prices of movies and soda remain constant. 2) The budget line shifts leftward, but its slope does not change.
  15. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model Instructor Notes: 1) Cost, C, falls from $30 to $15 while the prices of labor and capital remain constant. 2) The isocost line shifts leftward, but its slope does not change.
  16. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model
  17. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model
  18. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model
  19. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model
  20. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model
  21. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model
  22. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model
  23. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model
  24. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model A country will export the goods whose production is intensive in the factor with which that country is abundantly endowed. Home is K abundant, S is K intensive.
  25. Why does the ratio 0D/OR represent the proportionate increase in the price of T? This is a bit hard to see at first. Suppose that R and W (and C) rose by the same proportion as P T . Then the isocost line would shift in (parallel) to be tangent at R. This lower quantity of T costs $1 to produce, and would sell for $1. Since price equals marginal cost equals average cost, the increase in cost will equal the increase in price. Thus 0D/0R represents the proportionate increase in price. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model
  26. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model Why does the ratio 0D/OR represent the proportionate increase in the price of T? This is a bit hard to see at first. Suppose that R and W (and C) rose by the same proportion as P T . Then the isocost line would shift in (parallel) to be tangent at R. This lower quantity of T costs $1 to produce, and would sell for $1. Since price equals marginal cost equals average cost, the increase in cost will equal the increase in price. Thus 0D/0R represents the proportionate increase in price.
  27. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model This proof does not seem as clear as the one I already presented. Thus the only advantage of presenting it might be to reinforce the students’ understanding of isoquants/isocosts and their understanding of the other theorems.
  28. Eastwood&apos;s ECO 486 Notes Isocost lines, isoquant curves, and the HO model