SlideShare uma empresa Scribd logo
1 de 53
Baixar para ler offline
1
Reviving the European Union’s Emissions
Trading System: Structural Reform of the EU
ETS
Master's Thesis
MSc Political Science: International Relations
Author: Miles Knight
June 2016
First Reader and Thesis Supervisor: Prof Dr J.H. Zeitlin
Second Reader: Dr. P. Schleifer
2
Acknowledgements
The writer of this thesis would like to thank Prof Dr J.H. Zeitlin for supervising this project. Professor
Zeitlin has provided excellent intellectual insight into the evolution of governance. Furthermore, he
has also provided the inspiration for researching this topic by providing an outstanding overview of
current political developments within European Union.
I would also like to thank the Dr. P. Schleifer for taking giving up time to be the second reader of this
thesis.
Finally, I would like to thank and express my gratitude to all six interviewees who kindly gave up a
great deal of their time and knowledge towards for the purpose of this research.
List of acronyms
COM – European Commission
DG CLIMA – Directorate-General Climate Action [a subsidiary of the European Commission]
EG – Experimentalist Governance
ENGO – Environmental Non-Governmental Organisation
ENVI – The European Parliament’s Environment, Public Health and Food Safety Committee of MEPs
EU ETS – European Union Emissions Trading System
EUA – EU Allowance [GHG permit]
GB – Interest-Group Bargaining
GHG – Green House Gases
IGB – Intergovernmental Bargaining
IPD – Institutional Path Dependency
ITRE – The European Parliament’s Industry, Energy and Research Committee of MEPs
MEP – Member of European Parliament
MS – Member State
MSR – Market Stability Reserve
NFG – New Forms of Governance
OMC – Open Method of Co-ordination
3
Contents
1. Introduction .................................................................................................................5
1.1 Climate change and the complexity of transnational mitigation .....................................................6
1.2 A transnational climate mitigation instrument for the European Union: Directive 96/61/EC - the
EU ETS .....................................................................................................................................................7
1.3 Problem formulation & research questions .....................................................................................8
2. Theoretical framework & literature............................................................................. 11
2.1 New forms of governance in the EU [NFG].....................................................................................11
2.2 Experimentalist Governance [EG]...................................................................................................12
2.3 Approaches to political bargaining: interest-group bargaining [GB] and intergovernmental
bargaining [IGB] ....................................................................................................................................14
2.4 Institutional path dependency [IPD]...............................................................................................16
2.6 Cap-and-trade systems, their strengths and weaknesses ..............................................................17
2.7 The Market Stability Reserve..........................................................................................................19
2.8 Section summary; a gap for new research......................................................................................20
3. Methodology.............................................................................................................. 21
3.1 Data.................................................................................................................................................22
4. The 2050 roadmap and the EUA surplus imbalance ..................................................... 23
4.1 Defining long-term goals for the EU ETS: the 2050 roadmap.........................................................24
4.2 A milestones for the 2050 roadmap: the 2030 framework ............................................................25
4.3 The carbon market crisis: EUA surplus imbalance..........................................................................26
5. Short-term structural reform of the EU ETS: ‘Back-loading’.......................................... 27
5.1 Initiating preliminary deliberation of EU ETS structural reform.....................................................28
5.2 Launching a stakeholder consultation on review of EUA auctioning – presenting the option of
‘Back-loading’........................................................................................................................................30
5.3 The Co-Decision Procedure and 'Back-loading' ..............................................................................31
4
6. Long-term structural reform of the EU ETS: the Market Stability Reserve .................... 33
6.1 Preliminary deliberation of strengthening the EU ETS ...................................................................33
6.2 Stakeholder consultation on structural options to strengthen EU ETS – presenting the MSR ......36
6.3 Expert meetings on EU ETS structural reform – refining the MSR .................................................38
6.4 The Co-Decision Procedure and the Market Stability Reserve.......................................................39
6.4.1 The impact of the European Council upon the final outcome.....................................................40
6.4.2 The impact of the European Parliament upon the final outcome...............................................41
7. The Market Stability Reserve and the road to 2050 ..................................................... 43
7.1 Driving down greenhouse gas emissions through decarbonisation...............................................45
8. Conclusions ................................................................................................................ 45
9. Bibliography ............................................................................................................... 48
5
1. Introduction
Climate change is a global issue that requires transnational solutions. At the core of the issue is the
anthropogenic emission of greenhouse gases which are driving force behind global warming. For
decades the international community has attempted to resolve the issue through intergovernmental
bargaining, nonetheless many of these attempts have fallen short of their targets [i.e. the Kyoto
Protocol]. The European Union has taken it upon itself to set an example of how to abate
greenhouse gas emissions in a transnational setting. Sitting at the heart of this ambitious plan is
European Commission who has designed a long-term framework for transitioning towards becoming
a low-carbon economy. Imperative to this vision is the goal to cut greenhouse gas emissions by 80-
95%% below 1990 levels, by the year 2050 (European Commission, 2011). Central to achieving this is
the EU Emissions Trading System [EU ETS]; established in 2005 as the “cornerstone” of the EU’s GHG
emission reduction strategy. This economic instrument utilises the concept of the market to find and
set prices for CO2 allowances that are distributed by the Commission, either freely or at auction (EU
Commission, 2013: 2) (Skjærseth & Wettestad, 2010). During each phase of the trading, allowances
are removed from the market to reduce the ceiling, encouraging businesses within the system to
make deeper investments in clean technology to avoid paying for expensive carbon permits.
In practice, the market has failed in its most recent phase beginning in 2013. Surpluses of
allowances were made available due to low demand for fossil fuels throughout the 2008 financial
crisis, as a result, allowance prices have plummeted from 30 Euro/tCO2 to levels below 5 Euro/tCO2,
and have failed to recover ever since (Schopp, et al. 2015). To resolve this chronic issue, extensive
structural reforms have been requested by stakeholders through dialogue with the European
Commission, and carbon market experts. Resultantly, the ‘Back-loading’ amendment to auction
regulation was adopted as the short-term solution in 2014 to take immediate effect, followed by the
Market Stability Reserve [MSR]; adopted as the long-term solution and due to operate indefinitely
from in 2019. Whilst a long-term solution has been established, the reform process has been
delayed blocking parties in the European Council, rejected proposals by the European Parliament
and lobbying by numerous stakeholders. In an amongst the political deadlock local stakeholders
including trade organisations, environmental NGOs and market experts have worked towards
shaping the final outcome of reform alongside member state representatives.
The final outcome [the MSR] is expected resolve the surplus imbalance, improve the systems
functionality, and enable the EU ETS to remain as the EU’s first-best policy instrument for achieving
the 2050 roadmap goals. With the hopes of the EU’s climate goals pinned on the MSR, this thesis
aims to investigate is the ability of mechanism to revive the EU ETS. In order to do so this research
6
determines the extent to which interest-group and intergovernmental bargaining, institutional path
dependency, or recursive learning from past failures and local stakeholders can explain the
development and functionality of the final outcome. Subsequently, the argument presented in this
paper is that features of experimentalism such as recursive learning from past failures and local
stakeholders can help to create more robust reforms; reducing the negative aspects of uncertainty
and political bargaining between member states, trade organisations and the European Commission.
In theory, this promotes stability within the EU ETS creating a safer environment in which market
actors can invest in low-carbon future.
1.1 Climate change and the complexity of transnational mitigation
Anthropogenic emissions of green-house gases are now at the highest recorded level in human
history. Scientists across the globe have observed and proven with ‘very high’ certainty that the
warming of the climate system over the previous 60 years has been catalysed by anthropogenic
emissions of GHGs. Carbon dioxide forms the largest concentration of all GHG gases in the
atmosphere much of which is emitted through processes of combustion in engines in the generation
of power. For this reason it is deducible that transport, power generation and the industrial sectors
across the world form the crux of CO2 emissions, thus they have become the prime target for
mitigation efforts by governments and civil society. The urgent need for mitigation stems from the
agreed need to contain rising global temperatures within a 2 degree centigrade threshold. If this
threshold is exceeded, the damage upon natural systems will be catastrophic and irreversible having
severe knock on effects in the human environment that will ultimately claim more lives than it has
already (IPCC, 2014).
In many senses, proving through science that humankind is to blame for the current rise in
global temperatures was comparatively straight forward; the step of generating global mitigation
efforts is much harder. The mere notion of mitigation against climate change is one that has incurred
great deliberation based upon historic, economic and philosophical arguments. The core of the
dilemma is that no single state, company or section of society can or will bear the blame for the
human races’ epic environmental blight. Effectively, this has led to a game of pass the GHG buck; the
ramifications of this have meant that international climate negotiations have stalled numerous times
until the late efforts of the COP21 meeting in Paris signalled a breakthrough. Meanwhile, industry
and by extension its customers have escaped until recently from being held accountable for their
role in inducing climate change. From and economic standpoint, the environmental impacts of
7
trading and consumption is an externality that has failed to be recognised and factored into the cost
of goods, this has been referred to as “the greatest market failure the world has ever seen” (Stern,
2006: 1) (Callon, 2009). This is a situation that cannot persist if we wish to escape an impending
tragedy of the commons catalysed by climate change (Hardin, 1968).
1.2 A transnational climate mitigation instrument for the European Union:
Directive 96/61/EC - the EU ETS
The EU produces 10% of global emissions, yet it has proudly striven to become the international
leader in climate change mitigation efforts (European Commission, 2011). By 2005 the United
Nations had hosted ten climate change conferences with almost no progress as a result. The Kyoto
Protocol had been signed in 1997 but did not enter into effect until 2005 with the omission of two
huge polluters; the US and China (Victor, 2011, chapter 7). However, in this same year, the EU
launched its pilot phase of the world’s first emissions trading system, a ‘cap and trade’ system
designed to reduce GHG emissions across Europe by harnessing the power of markets to trade
emission allowances. The EU ETS became to be the “cornerstone” of the European Union’s efforts to
reduce its own emissions ahead of the rest of the world, with the ambition of leading by example as
the world’s first and largest carbon market (European Commission, 2013) (Skjærseth & Wettestad,
2009).
The EU ETS works through the setting of a cap on the level of GHGs that can be emitted
across industrial sectors with high carbon dioxide [CO2], nitrous oxide [N2O] and perfluorocarbons
[PFC] emissions. These sectors include European energy and power, manufacturers, aviation
operators within the Europe, and other high emitting business confederations. At present, the EU
ETS spans 28 member states plus Iceland, Norway and Lichtenstein spanning 11,000 power
installations and manufacturing plants. This means the system covers approximately 45% of the
zones total emissions (European Commission, 2013).
The cap is reduced on an annual basis in order to achieve a transition to a low-carbon
economy. The goals for this have been set in the EU’s ‘2050 roadmap’ which demands an 80%
minimum cut in greenhouse gas emissions compared to 1990 (European Commission, 2011). Before
this target can be reached, a 40% reduction target must be met as a milestone laid out in the 2030
climate & energy framework (European Commission, 2014). Allowances for GHG emissions
representing one tonne of CO2 each, can be bought and sold by companies in the carbon market
8
within the limits of the allowance cap. Theoretically, this provides flexibility for the companies
involved, allowing them to choose when and how they cut their emissions in order to rely upon
buying fewer allowances [increasing cost efficiency] (European Commission, 2013).
The theory is that putting a price on carbon through cap-and-trade forces companies either
to incur the cost of emitting GHGs either by paying for their emissions at a market rate, or by
adopting clean technology to abate emissions; avoiding the need for more allowances. The higher
the price of the EU Allowances [EUAs], the stronger the signal is to invest in clean, low-carbon
technologies. Essentially, the system catalyses climate mitigation through the regulation of GHGs
under a market setting (European Commission, 2014).
1.3 Problem formulation & research questions
The EU ETS has been designated as the European Commission’s first-best policy for reducing GHG
emissions. With this in mind it was designed to achieve the EUs commitment to the Kyoto Protocol
between 2008 and 2012, with the ultimate goal of supporting the Union in achieving its 2020 climate
and energy targets (European Commission, 2013). The prime goals of 2020 were to achieve a 20%
cut in GHG emissions (from 1990 levels), to make 20% transition towards the use of renewables in
the energy market, and to produce a 20% improvement in energy efficiency (European Commision,
2009). By and large the EU ETS is on track to do play its part in this with an 18% reduction in GHG
emissions across the carbon market (European Commission, 2014).
Beyond 2020, the future of the EU ETS as the most effective tool for achieving EU climate
and energy policy is becoming clouded. The exogenous shock that was the 2008 financial crisis
exposed new faults in the architecture and governance of the system, in the event of a crash in
global markets that reduced economic growth. Due to this event, the price of fossil fuels collapsed as
a result of a decrease in demand across the industrial and transport sectors (Grosjean, et al., 2014)
(Koch, et al., 2014). Simultaneously, regulators continued to issue allowances creating a surplus in
the market at a time when fossil fuels had become cheaper. With these two factors combined, it
became economically efficient for EU ETS sectors to revert from clean energy technologies towards
using old fossil fuel base technology. EUA prices had plummeted from €30 per tCO2 to levels below
€5 per tCO2, facilitating a slow-down in the EUs transition towards adopting renewables (Schopp, et
al., 2015).
9
Moving closer towards the year 2020, the EU has looked onwards to establish milestones for
achieving the ‘2050 roadmap’ goals, intensifying and extending the EUs climate mitigation efforts
further. The reformulated targets require at least 40% cuts in greenhouse gas emissions (from 1990
levels, a minimum 27% share for renewable energy, and at least 27% improvement in energy
efficiency by 2030 (European Commission, 2014). However, after the carbon market report of 2012,
it became clear that the EU ETS was not functioning well enough to achieve any meaningful climate
goals set beyond 2020 (European Commission, 2012). Despite this, the EU ETS is still set to remain as
the Commissions key tool for achieving the 2030 goals [and by extension the 2050 goals and the
Paris agreement] prompting serious questions about the operation and governance of the system,
even with structural reforms underway.
With the decline in functionality of the EU ETS, the future of climate mitigation in the EU has
become uncertain, a precarious problem if the EU wishes to continue as a ‘climate leader’ into the
future to meet its own 2050 goals and map out a strategy for meeting the Paris agreement. Despite
structural amendments in the form of ‘Back-loading’ [Commission Regulation No 176/2014], the
surplus crisis is ongoing with EUA prices having hit a new 16 month low in February 2016 of €4.63
per tCO2 and are unlikely to recover significantly until the operation of the Market Stability Reserve
[MSR] (European Commission, 2014) (EEX, 2016). The ‘Back-loading’ amendment to the EU ETS
auctioning regulation is a short-term measure that reduces the volume of EUAs being auctioned in
incremental steps; 400 million allowances in 2014, 300 million in 2015 and 200 million in 2016.
These EUAs are withheld from being auctioned and have now been placed in the Market Stability
Reserve. Effectively, this reduced the surplus of allowances on the market, driving up their price
(European Commission, 2014). Whilst the ‘Back-loading’ was only short-term solution it has failed to
perform as expected whilst the long-term solution to the market imbalance [the MSR] is due to start
operation two years later than originally intended within the initial proposals. Meanwhile,
stakeholders are still debating the credibility of the MSR mechanisms and its finer details. The latest
development to the reform process is the launching of legal proceedings by Poland to sue the
European Commission for making structural amendments within a trading period that it argues will
damage operational and investment plans of Polish businesses (Republic of Poland, 2015).
This series of recent events are in effect empirical evidence that underpin many of the
critiques of ‘cap-and-trade’ systems as a cost-effective means of climate mitigation. Likewise, the
structural reforms have carved a deeper rift between the actors committed to climate change
mitigation, and those who are not; incumbent polluters (EurActiv, 2015). The problem presented in
this thesis is a question of political bargaining and efficiency in resolving the carbon market’s
10
instability, and more importantly, in meeting the EUs 2050 climate goals. To this end, this research
aims to ascertain whether the structural reforms past [‘Back-loading’] and present [MSR] can resolve
the EUA surplus crisis and drive clean investment through an investigation of the political process
that has eventually produced ‘Decision (EU) 2015/1814’ – the Market Stability Reserve (European
Commission, 2015).
In doing so, it is critical to ascertain which stakeholders have had the most influential role in
the development of the reforms, and to match the views of various stakeholders with the final
structural amendments that have been established. The purpose of this is to determine whether or
not the European Commission has incorporated experimentalist features into its policymaking
process through recursive learning from past failures and local stakeholders (Sabel & Zeitlin, 2008)
(Sabel & Zeitlin, 2012). Arguably this is a mark of progress in developing a more stable and efficient
system that will ensure the reduction of the EUs GHG emissions (Van Empel, 2014). Reflexive style
governance with experimental features is vital for developing an ‘in vivo’ style market, one which
relies heavily upon testing new institutional arrangements to improve functionality and the achieve
climate mitigation goals that have been set (Callon, 2009). Furthermore, as discussed in the previous
sections of this introduction, climate change mitigation is a complex and transnational issue that
requires learning, the capacity problem-solve and above all, co-operation through deliberation.
These are integral features of ‘experimentalism’ which this investigation aims to disclose in the
governance of the EU ETS (Sabel & Zeitlin, 2008) (Sabel & Zeitlin, 2012). Thus, the experimentalist
theoretical approach has been focused upon with the aim of establishing if it exists, and to what
extent it could improve the governance of the EU ETS.
Whilst preliminary research suggests that in theory, experimentalist features could prove to
key for governing markets, it is also understood that other theoretical approaches may also explain
the development of the reform process and the established outcomes. Policy reform of regulation
within the EU is a complex process which requires the approval of stakeholders across multiple
levels, which often have competing interests from each other and the European Commission. In light
of this the institutional path dependency, intergovernmental and interest-group bargaining
theoretical approaches will also be used to analyse the impact of competing stakeholders upon the
established policy outcomes. Combining these approaches with experimentalism will help to divulge
the evolutionary pattern of the reform process to determine how the EU ETS is being recovered and
in what way this is shaped by the governance of the system.
11
To frame the problem that has been formulated, the research question of this thesis asks:
What best explains the development of the structural reforms to the EU’s Emission Trading System:
interest-group and intergovernmental bargaining, institutional path dependency, or recursive
learning from local stakeholders and past failures?
2. Theoretical framework & literature
This section will detail and analyse the theories and approaches that will underpin the argument
throughout this thesis. Analyses of new forms of governance, experimentalism and classic theories
of EU integration such as institutional path dependency and intergovernmental bargaining will
provide the theoretical framework. Following this the theory behind cap-and-trade will be discussed
in the context of the EU ETS so that the strengths and weaknesses of the system are exposed in light
of the broader argument over the efficiency of cap-and-trade. Throughout, there will be references
to key literature related to each section, but also exposure of gaps in research that this investigation
intends to contribute towards closing.
2.1 New forms of governance in the EU [NFG]
The crux of this research is an investigation into the approach of governance and decision-making
that best explains the EU ETS structural reform process. Focus will in part be placed recursive
learning from past failures and local stakeholders which can loosely be associated with the features
of ‘new forms of governance’ [NFGs]. Scholarly discussion surrounding the development of NFGs
arose from the establishment of the ‘open method of co-ordination’ [OMC] instrument in 2000 as a
part of the Lisbon strategy. This framework induced economic cooperation between EU member
states that were unwilling to yield policymaking powers to European institutions. The purpose of the
design was to reduce political deadlock in the council through intergovernmental deliberation and
co-evaluation of progress. Under the OMC member states must jointly search for and establish
common goals, create instruments for measuring these goals, then benchmark performance through
comparative studies and sharing of best practices. Essentially, this entails learning from each other’s
progress through peer review. Standing at the heart of this process is the Commission who monitor
progress whilst relying on ‘soft law’ to encourage compliance (Craig & De Búrca, 2011, chp. 6)
12
(Kohler-Koch & Rittberger, 2006) (European Commission, 2016). Since the development of the OMC
the EUs approach to governance has evolved to cope with new transnational challenges across an
array of areas including the environment. Research into NFGs has expanded to analyse this
evolution.
What defines NFGs and separates them from traditional hierarchical forms of governance is
the faith they place in ‘soft law’. Soft laws are regulations or directives without sanctions for non-
compliance; instead they coerce actors through mutual learning and socialization. In tougher
situations they are enforced through the shadow of hierarchy; usually in the form of an implicit
threat of public intervention such as legal action or tightening of regulations to settle the concern of
non-compliance. Crucial to NFG is cooperation by higher actors units with local actors such as private
organisations. Local actors are incorporated into the policy and decision-making process with the
role of educating their retrospective member states on frontline issues, evaluating their proposals,
or the policy goals of other high level actors. Whilst actors at all levels are included in this process of
deliberation, the subsidiarity principal requires that member states hold the final vote on each
legislative proposal which can lead to inter-governmental bargaining [see section 2.3] (Braun, 2009)
(Craig & De Búrca, 2011, chp. 6) (Kohler-Koch & Rittberger, 2006).
The conceptualisation of ‘new forms of governance’ provides a reasonable framework from
which to approach the research questions of this thesis. At best it provides an interpretation of EU
governance as shifting towards the reliance upon ‘soft law’, decentralised decision making including
the input of actors at all levels, and the socialisation of institutional and governmental actors with
local actors (Kohler-Koch & Rittberger, 2006). Cooperating with actors at multiple levels could
produce a more balanced and effective reform that is functional and has popular support. However,
new interpretations of EU policymaking have been established in the form of ‘experimentalist
governance’ which could provide a more relevant framework from which the problem formulated in
this thesis can be investigated.
2.2 Experimentalist Governance [EG]
Sabel and Zeitlin have identified what they refer to as a new architecture of experimentalist
governance [EG] in the EU, one that closely resembles the concept of ‘new forms of governance’. EG
shares many of its principals with those noted in the previous section, in particular the emphasis
upon the freedom of lower-level units to enact upon policy directives and regulations in a strategy of
13
their choosing. Autonomy of this scale is granted on the premise that lower-level or local actors
must report back to each other under a peer review system, benchmarked against each other’s
performance with the objective of meeting commonly agreed goals (Sabel & Zeitlin, 2008, 2012).
Experimentalist governance, in the same way as NFGs, separates itself from ‘old’ hierarchical
forms of governance through its unique theorisation of the way in which decision-making processes
are beginning to evolve. The key difference is the integration of lower-level units into the
socialization process. This refers to the practice of inviting local regulators, ministries, experts or
consultants [i.e. carbon market analysts] at the forefront of their fields to analyse the progress of
other actors and to provide state-of the art feedback to higher-level units [i.e. the European
Commission]. Representatives of interest groups may also take part in committee style events in
order to provide informal analysis, diversifying the deliberation process. This multi-level integration
of actors enables local units to influence the final decisions of higher-level units (Sabel & Zeitlin,
2008, 2010) (Braun, 2009). Investigating networking between multiple levels has formed an essential
part of this study since the European Commission must work to understand lower level stakeholders’
expertise and opinions. Without this, it would be unwise to govern a cap-and-trade system in which
stakeholders can’t trust the market or the designers of the instrument. Whilst extensive networking
is crucial, there are no set institutional arrangements in experimentalist architectures, so long as
lower-level units receive autonomy to achieve the stated goals [i.e. the 2050 Roadmap; see section
3.2] in return for participation in the performance/peer review process.
Perhaps the most important feature of EG for the argument of this investigation is its
emphasis on the response of decision makers towards reducing the threat of uncertainty. In
situations where uncertainty is persistent [i.e. carbon market instability and the unquantifiable
threat of climate change], the decision-maker will work to understand the conditions that produce
uncertainty and minimise them through the peer review process. This includes recursive learning
from past failures, dynamic approaches to reform, and regular revision of goals, metrics and
implementation methods to reflect what has been learnt through the peer review process. This
process encourages actors to pursue the goals that have been set in a new environment which
demands learning through difference or “joint exploration of possibilities” (Sabel & Zeitlin, 2012,
pg.3). Ultimately, the EG approach to policymaking increases the capacity with which a community
of actors can achieve goals, and react to reduce any uncertainty to depress any conflict between
competing actor interests (Sabel & Zeitlin, 2012) (Verdun, 2012).
Experimentalist governance is a relatively new concept that already has a flurry of empirical
examples to underpin its theorisations. They traverse a wide range of policy fields from finance, to
14
food safety, forestry, chemicals, energy regulation and environmental protection (Zeitlin, 2015).
With reference to the latter domain, perhaps the most outstanding empirical example is the
Montreal Protocol. The Vienna Convention for the Protection of the Ozone Layer was heralded as
one of the most successful international environmental protection agreements to date, to which
strength is owed particularly to its experimentalist architecture. Amongst other features, the
inclusion of a Technology and Economic Assessment Panel cooperating with a local industry based
Technical Options Committees helped monitor and review progress in order to suggest amendments
to the protocol. The success of this system became evident through the quick results that prevented
atmospheric Ozone depletion through the combined efforts of 197 states (De Búrca, et al., 2014).
Thus, in relation to this research it is important to understand the advantages of EG and what it can
provide for environmental policy domains that face high levels of uncertainty [EU ETS Structural
Reforms]. Preliminary research suggest that traces of EG has been incorporated into the EU ETS due
to its close development by the Commission in partnership with local level units such as experts
from consultancies, ENGOs and private companies (Braun, 2009). However, searching for EG
architecture in correspondence with the success of policy outcomes could provide new evidence on
the effectiveness of EG within environmental regulation. Here lies a gap in the literature to
investigate the prominence of recursive learning from past failures and local stakeholders in the
context of the EU’s first-best climate mitigation instrument, the EU ETS.
2.3 Approaches to political bargaining: interest-group bargaining [GB] and
intergovernmental bargaining [IGB]
The ultimate goal of this thesis is to determine the extent to which the structural reforms can
resolve the EUA imbalance and help attain the 2050 climate and energy goals. Whilst the established
outcome [the MSR] sets a benchmark from which to analyse the political decision-making process
and assess the impact of varying stakeholders and institutional arrangements. In light of this, the
European Commission employed extensive use of consultations with local stakeholders. Each of
these stakeholders has its own agenda that may be different from that of the European Commission,
Council or Parliament. Thus, lobbying is likely to be present as local actors bargain to a produce
public good [a functional EU ETS] that generates a good return for the political and financial
investment (Tollison, 2001). In order to understand the effects of local actors, the interest-group
bargaining [GB] approach will be applied to provide a framework from which to analyse the
behaviour of local stakeholders and the effect of their bargaining upon the final outcome of reform.
15
GB in many cases is likely to manifest in similar policy discussions as EG where local stakeholders are
keen to bargain over their views throughout the deliberation process (Cutcher-Gershenfeld, 2014,
chp. 6).
Cutcher-Gershenfeld has compressed GB into 5 consecutive phases that detail the process of
actors’ behaviour in negotiations, the most relevant of which are detailed here. During phase one;
actors identify their own interests creating multiple plans for each whilst anticipating those of their
opponents/counterparts. Phase three, actors produce initial statements defining their core interests,
posing questions to other actors then co-operate to find common interests options. Phase four,
actors search for mutual benefits across the range of issues. Following this, drafting of agreements
begins to provide clarity over sides agreements and differences. The fifth and final phase, actors
work to establish joint-implementation processes using mutually agreeable metrics for measuring
both sides progress (Cutcher-Gershenfeld, 2014, chp. 6).
To date, GB has not yet been used to analyse the structural reform process which provides a
gap to investigate and present empirical findings on the impact of interest-group bargaining.
However, research suggests that within the EU interest-group bargaining is influencing policy
outcomes, particularly environmental directives. Generally, interest groups will mobilize and try to
align themselves with national governments; they have a permanent seat in negotiations combined
with voting power. Thus, if a government shares the views of an interest-group it is in that groups
advantage to lobby through government officials. However, if a government does not have aligned
views with the interest group, the group may seek to directly lobby the European Council or
Parliament or do so through a wider European group i.e. a European trade association or local
institutions with European connections (Callanan, 2011).
Whilst GB is likely to be present, the co-decision procedure means the European Council
have to agree with the European Parliament and any amendments they have made. In effect, the
Council makes the final decision on whether or not an amendment is inscribed into law. Therefore
the intergovernmental bargaining approach provides insight into the behaviour of member states
such as Poland who have recently launched legal proceedings to sue the Commission due to its
dissatisfaction with the early start date to the MSR [2019 as opposed to 2021] (Republic of Poland,
2015). In the context of the EU, intergovernmental bargaining theory is centred on member states
and their ability to influence the policy outcome by pushing their agenda through the deliberation
process. Essentially the agenda of each state reflects its domestic structure. States with similar
preferences may align with each other if there are links between their policy goals or bargaining
behaviour in the decision making procedure, but generally it is assumed that they will act through
16
rational choice to achieve what is best for their nation’s interests when negotiating EU legislation
(Saam & Sumpter, 2009).
A central assumption of this theory is that political infighting or socialization between
member states can shape the final policy outcome. Member states are aware of the commissions
influence in policy implementation and seek to alter this in order to restrict the Commission from
commanding member states (Skjærseth & Wettestad, 2010). After reviewing the Commission’s
proposals, state representatives will often strike a deal with the Commission to agree with their
proposals on the basis that particular set decision-making procedures are abided by [e.g. a re-
balancing the principal-agent relationship in future agreements] (Blom-Hansen & Brandsma, 2009)
(Thatcher & Coen, 2008). The intergovernmental approach has been applied to EU ETS reform during
previous phases. For example, Eastern European member states have been found to have
significantly shaped the policy outcome of reform processes during the early pilot phases [2005-
2007 and 2008-2012]. However, there is a gap for using this approach to analyse the recent
structural reforms that have produced the ‘Back-loading’ and MSR amendments, where there is lack
of literature covering the new reforms (Skjærseth & Wettestad, 2010).
2.4 Institutional path dependency [IPD]
The EU is constantly evolving; it is has not yet departed fully from ‘old’ hierarchical forms of
governance. Furthermore, despite a movement towards NFGs and EG across EU policymaking, the
European Commission remains a fundamental designer and coordinator of policy within the
structure of the European Union. Thus, processes of reform may occur in path dependent ways as
old institutional structures such as the European Commission and Council continue to mould or even
restrict the policy strategies of new interest groups [e.g. local stakeholders and experts]. Using a
historical institutionalist approach will allow for analysis of political outcomes via actors rule abiding
or interest maximising behaviour as opposed to recursive learning through past failures and local
stakeholders, features of EG (Thatcher & Coen, 2008) (Della Porta & Keating, 2008, chpater 7).
With regard to the EU regulatory space, historical institutionalism has been cited as the most
fitting approach for detailing the political layering that has occurred through the timescale of
reforms and debates that have taken place. Thatcher and Coen argue that new institutions [rules of
law/structural arrangements] tend to be an extension of the old with added enhancements since
existing actors do not wish to concede power to new competing actors. Therefore they are likely to
17
be opposed to radical new institutions [e.g. structural reform options] that may alter the balance of
power despite having the opportunity to solve past policy failures, this is often referred to as
institutional path dependency [IDP] (Thatcher & Coen, 2008).
2.6 Cap-and-trade systems, their strengths and weaknesses
This section builds upon the brief introduction to cap-and-trade found in section 1.2 by analysing the
deep range of literature discussing the theory underpinning cap-and-trade, its strengths and
weaknesses. Generally speaking, there are two prime instruments for encouraging climate
mitigation; economic instruments [e.g. market systems such as cap-and-trade] or regulatory
instruments [e.g. directives that demand the adoption of particular technologies or practices].
Theoretically, price based economic instruments such as cap-and-trade provide the incentive for
companies to invest autonomously in clean technologies in order to avoid incurring economic costs.
Conversely, regulatory instruments are intended to command control of companies’ emissions,
performance or technology standards. This reduces the level of autonomy afforded to companies
when working towards regulatory goals (O'Donnell, 2012)(Bergek & Berggren, 2014).
Markets are increasingly being exploited as an economic instrument of choice. They have
strong qualities that have produced rapid economic and social transitions across the world in a short
period of history. On the down side, externalities such as the environment have been neglected for
generations, exposing the weaknesses of their design. However, one solution to the shortfalls of
markets is to harness the power of the market itself through a re-design of the socio-technical
structures and regimes from which they have been produced (Callon, 2009) (Bergek & Berggren,
2014). Cap-and-trade is an example of this, first conceptualised in the 1970’s as solution to air
pollution in the U.S. it was eventually tested in 1977 as a part of the Clean Air Act (EPA, 2016). Since
their conception, cap-and-trade systems have been employed across the globe from the EU ETS to
the California, Tokyo, Korean and Chinese Cap-and-Trade programs; all of which are market
instruments to reduce GHG emissions and catalyse ecological modernisation. Now that the Paris
agreement has been adopted at the COP21 negotiations, cap-and-trade systems are likely to be
adopted in greater numbers across the globe in a bid to abate climate change (ICAP, 2016).
The EU ETS is a pioneering experiment that takes a step beyond the rudimentary design of
the clean air act or laboratory testing of markets. The EUs Emissions Trading System is an ‘in vivo’
experiment that has been founded and operated using a trial and error based learning system
[learning through each new time phase]. Each phase of the system is monitored and reviewed in an
18
experimental approach with the aim of developing a system that increases in cost-efficiency and
mitigation effectiveness. The very architecture of the EU ETS has been designed to be experimental
with fixed review dates and temporary tests. Theoretically this approach should reduce uncertainty
in the market through deliberation, learning and progressive results (Callon, 2009) (MacKenzie,
2009). Despite the experimental nature of the EU ETS, it is argued that the governance structures
operating these systems are still “cruelly lacking” in leadership that needs to be critical, impartial
and willing to be remain open to novel questions or views (Callon, 2009: 2). This is arguably more
important than the features of a market itself; the way in which it is operated, governed and
reformed. This argument supports the aims of this research to investigate recursive learning from
past failures and local stakeholder engagement within the reforms.
Across EU ETS sectors the Union has achieved an 18% reduction in GHG emissions relative to
1990 accompanied by a 13% rise in the share of renewables in 2012 (European Commission, 2014).
Additionally, results show that the system has produced a significant increase in research and
development in relation to projects for ETS sectors [Carbon Capture Storage being the biggest
breakthrough]. Another advantage of the EU ETS is that having an internal market with a Union wide
carbon price cuts out disparities that would occur between states due to individual national policies
that could create a ‘two-track’ Europe that develops at different speeds (Egenhofer, et al., 2011).
Overall, the most prominent success of the EU ETS has been in disseminating established clean
technologies to reduce GHG emissions across industrial sectors without free permit allowances
(Bergek & Berggren, 2014).
Regardless of the strengths of cap-and-trade, it is by no means the ‘silver bullet’ in the battle
against climate change. Theoretically, they have powerful benefits as discussed, but on the flip side
they are accompanied by a series of weaknesses some of which are inherent and immutable. Sabel
and Simon provide a good overview of the most prominent weakness, the first of which is the issue
of GHG regulation. Emissions of GHGs can be measured effectively since it is known through
scientific studies how many of each GHG compound can be expected to enter the atmosphere
through which polluting activities. However, what cannot be calculated with high accuracy is the
level of risk that each GHG will carry towards the environment due to the labyrinth of externalities
caused by air pollution. In effect, this undermines the validity of carbon pricing and the setting of
GHG reduction goals (Sabel & Simon, 2011) (IPCC, 2014). This is a particular problem if the EU wishes
to achieve its 2050 goals since they can only serve as approximate targets as opposed to being
definitive goals that can be measured and monitored accurately.
19
Secondly, market regulators must calculate the ancillary costs of GHG mitigation by second
guessing the scale and damage that could be caused to the environment by substitute pollutants.
These substitutes may be adopted by companies in place of the regulated ones [CO2, N2O and PFCs].
Empirical evidence of this could be witnessed in 2006. EUA prices crumpled as a result of regulators
setting the aggregate emissions target too high after miscalculating the ‘business as usual’ emissions
scenario. Resultantly the market price collapsed after regulators sent out the wrong price signals
(Sabel & Simon, 2011).
Thirdly, and perhaps most importantly, it remains unclear how potent a tool cap-and-trade
systems can be at generating ecological modernisation or transfers of new clean technologies into
the market. Due to the complex entanglement of renewable technology subsidies, fossil fuel taxes
and emissions trading, it is extremely hard to separate the effects of cap-and-trade from those of
other competing climate change abatement instruments (Skjærseth & Wettestad, 2010). There is
little empirical evidence to suggest that market-instruments are the superior option when compared
to environmental compliance instruments that demand clean technology transfers, in fact some
evidence suggests they are inferior (Sabel & Simon, 2011) (Bergek & Berggren, 2014). Furthermore,
it is argued that without the inclusion of the general public [individual consumption] from cap-and-
trade systems, it is harder to transfer small scale local technologies to make additional
improvements to abatement (Sabel & Simon, 2011).
2.7 The Market Stability Reserve
Central to the second research question of this study is the market stability reserve. This automatic
mechanism has been designed as a long-term solution to the structural imbalance of EUAs. Whilst
this mechanism is yet to be deployed, there is already a wide body of literature discussing its
strengths and weaknesses, all of which have critical effects upon the functionality of the EU ETS.
The MSR is an automatic quantity-based mechanism that removes EUAs from the market
based upon an upper threshold of 833 million. The MSR operates with a two year gap between the
trigger events [e.g. an economic recession] and the build-up of EUAs to in circulation [creating a
surplus imbalance], this gap allows for ex-ante assessment of the trigger event and an ex-post
analysis of its implications upon the future of the market. When the upper threshold of EUAs has
been reached, 12% of allowances in circulation are removed and placed into the reserve. The same
process is mirrored when there is a shortage of EUAs in the market based upon a lower threshold of
400 million allowances (Richstein, et al., 2015).
20
The intended effect of the MSR is to reduce price volatility however opponents of the MSR
have criticised some key assumptions made by the Commission in the design of the MSR. Hedging of
allowances by market actors is a pivotal process in the market which the MSR attempts to pre-empt.
However data on hedging does not have to be disclosed by companies’, therefore the MSR can only
react to hedging based upon presumptions of market actors behaviour. In reality this could lead to a
disconnect between the real hedging behaviour of companies’ versus the Commissions predictions.
The end result of this could be a slow reaction by the MSR leaving EUA prices too low (Richstein, et
al., 2015). It is also argued that the MSR will not increase the environmental effectiveness of the EU
ETS, it will only prevent it from failing, reducing the uptake of carbon intensive activities (Acworth,
2014).
Despite critiques of the reform, economists maintain that the MSR has the ability to enable
the EU to achieve its 2050 climate goals providing other areas of the EU ETS are tweaked to support
the MSR such as the linear reduction factor [LRF - the absolute decrease of EUAs, currently set at
1.74% per annum]. Increasing the LRF number to 2.55% would increase the effectiveness of the EU
ETS, this was one of the proposed options for reform by the Commission that lost to the MSR during
the consultation process (Hu, et al., 2015). Ultimately, the simplicity and transparency of the MSR
will provide market actors with clarity over the short-term outlook of the carbon market (Acworth,
2014).
2.8 Section summary; a gap for new research
To conclude, there is a breadth of research analysing the properties, strengths and weaknesses of
cap-and-trade systems, including the EU ETS. Nevertheless, there is an acute lack of research
investigating the institutional arrangements of the EU ETS moving into phase three and four [2013
and beyond]. Here lies a gap for analysing the governance of the system through the application of
intergovernmental bargaining, institutional path dependency, interest-group bargaining and EG.
Furthermore, within the literature there exists varying views of the MSR, its capacity to stabilize the
market and reduce GHG emissions. Parallel to questioning the governance of the EU ETS, critiques of
the MST open up questions over the policy outcomes of the structural reform process as well as the
process of reform itself. In order to close the research gap, this thesis will provide a renewed
overview of the EU ETS and the way in which it will continue to operate into the future in light of the
2050 climate and energy goals.
21
3. Methodology
Outcome-oriented process -tracing is the preeminent method of choice in this study, used to track
the timeline of developments throughout the EU ETS structural reforms to explain the outcome.
Within-case analysis has helped to highlight and understand the causal relationships between the
various actors. In particular it examines their preferences for particular policy amendments and the
outcome of their interactions with other co-operative/rival actors on the final policy establishments
by the Commission. Observations of political events recorded and published by the European
Commission such as the release of reports, position papers and consultations have been matched up
with changes to policy proposals and amendments to EU directives. This was carried out in
chronological order to trace key actors impacts upon the structural reforms in order to determine
which stakeholders have played the most significant role in altering the MSR design process. It also
builds an understanding of how the final design of the reforms matched with actors preferences in
the context of achieving the EUs 2050 goals. Ultimately this has helped determine which theoretical
framework- intergovernmental and interest-group bargaining, institutional path dependency, or
recursive learning from past failures and local stakeholders’ best describes the outcome of the
structural reform process (Beach & Pedersen, 2016) (Tansey, 2007).
Whilst political documents have formed the backbone of the study, tracking the timeline of
political/technocratic movements or release of actor’s opinions, elite interview data has
consolidated the information from this data through the following approaches. Firstly, they’ve been
utilised to triangulate the connections between various policy documents, academic literature and
the personal views of each interviewee to cross-check and reconstruct events throughout the reform
process. Secondly, they have established in greater detail the attitudes and beliefs of different
competing actors, enabling the research to highlight the motives of actors and the outcome of their
influence. Thirdly, elite interview data has provided wider context to the actions and attitudes of
large political groups or stakeholders, this is crucial given the sheer number involved in the reform
process who could not be investigated (Tansey, 2007). This enables the researcher to make
inferences about actors whose views may not otherwise be known, particularly in the case of the DG
CLIMA who have explicitly declined to comment on any issues outside of what has already been
published on their website.
A purposive sampling approach has been used to select elite interviewees from a pre-
defined list of actors; the DG CLIMA, ITRE, ENVI, permanent representatives of the European Council,
carbon market experts and local stakeholders such as ENGOs and trade associations. This enables
targeting of the most relevant actors who have remained close to the structural reform process or
22
hold a particularly great interest in the final amendments due to political or economic reasons. To
achieve a representative sample of the actor population, interviewees have been chosen from all
ends of the political spectrum based upon their public opinions of the MSR, proximity to the design
of the MSR [carbon market experts] and availability for interviewing (Tansey, 2007).
3.1 Data
The structural reform of the EU ETS has largely been a deliberative decision-making process led by
the European Commission, for which key official policy documentation is published online by the
Commission on its Climate Action website. This includes research, policy proposals and
amendments, impact assessments and legal directives will be used to trace and analyse the
Commissions learning and declarations. Some policy documentation may have remained undisclosed
by the commission; these include initial designs for reform produced prior to expert consultation.
Similar documentation types to those published by the commission have been used to interpret and
detail the position and role of MEPs and Council members involved in the reforms.
In conjunction with this, the Commission’s consultation process with EU ETS stakeholders
requires that all organisations that have provided feedback upon each proposal have their position
paper published online. These have been analysed to add depth to the study by detailing the
viewpoint of local non-governmental and industrial actors.
Expert interviews have been used to triangulate the knowledge gaps between the selection
of documents, and to investigate the deliberation process between actors. The interviewees are high
ranking representatives of organisations who have been involved at varying different levels and
stages of the reform process from ENGOs, trade associations and carbon market consultancies
employed as frontline ‘experts’ in the reform process. Unfortunately the European Commission
declined a request for interview due to the ongoing political sensitivity of the reform process, as well
as a number of MEPs who were contacted, including the rapporteur. As a result, the views expressed
in this thesis largely represent those held by local stakeholders through their interactions with
various European institutions, representatives or interest groups. Below is a list of the interviewees
that provided data for this research, including their in text citations.
23
(Interview 1, ENGO) – CEO & Founding Director of the Change Partnership and former senior
associate at E3G – role in the structural reform process: engaged in two public reform consultations
on the ‘Back-loading’ and MSR amendments, and led a coalition of market stakeholders for reform
of the EU ETS.
(Interview 2, energy trade association) – Environment Consultant for an energy trade association –
role in the structural reform process: engaged in two public reform consultations on the ‘Back-
loading’ and MSR amendments, interviewees organisation has an ongoing working relationship with
the its respective national government, the European Parliament and, EURELECTRC trade
association.
(Interview 3, coal trade association) – Public Affairs Manager for a coal and lignite trade association
– role in the structural reform process: engaged in two public reform consultations on the ‘Back-
loading’ and MSR amendments, also has an ongoing working relationship with DG CLIMA.
(Interview 4, expert) – Founder and Head of Market Analysis at a carbon market intelligence
organisation – role in the structural reform process: engaged in the ‘expert meeting on EU ETS
structural reform: Introduction of a market stability’ on 25/06/2014, has an ongoing working
relationship with DG CLIMA.
(Interview 5, expert) – Head of Applied Research at a ‘new finance’ company – role in the structural
reform process: engaged in the ‘expert meeting on EU ETS structural reform: Introduction of a
market stability’ on 25/06/2014.
(Interview 6, policy analyst) – Director of the Irish National Economic and Social Council – relation to
the EU ETS: has researched and published an investigation into the performance of carbon pricing
mechanism.
4. The 2050 roadmap and the EUA surplus imbalance
This section outlines the origins of the structural reforms process that provide a crucial backdrop to
the amendments of the EU ETS. Firstly, through analysis of the European Commission’s 2050
roadmap which has become the end-goal for the EU’s climate mitigation efforts, of which the EU ETS
has been designated as the first-best instrument for achieving this. Secondly, it will briefly explain
and analyse the cause and extent of the EUA surplus crisis that has led to a severe structural
24
imbalance of allowances. Ultimately this juncture prompted the need for emergency reform of the
EU ETS in order to meet the goals of the 2050 roadmap.
4.1 Defining long-term goals for the EU ETS: the 2050 roadmap
The first political juncture to spark movement towards structural reform began in the aftermath of
the 2050 roadmap consultations. Amidst the EUA surplus crisis, and in the light of pledges at COP15,
the European Commission [COM] began to design a long-term framework to help tackle the issue of
transnational climate change mitigation [see section 1.1]. After consulting stakeholders at multiple
levels, they produced a ‘Roadmap for moving to a competitive low carbon economy in 2050 - (08
Mar 2011)’ (European Commission, 2011). The 2050 roadmap was intended to provide the necessary
cuts in GHG emissions for the EU to play its own part in keeping global temperatures below a fatal 2
degree rise (IPCC, 2014).
Central to this communication was the emphasis upon transitioning towards becoming a
competitive low-carbon economy. The approach is that the EU ETS [amongst other instruments]
could drive investment in clean energy, improving energy efficiency to make a low-carbon transition
across the Union, particularly in the power sector. The key target for emissions was set at a Union
wide reduction of 80-95% of GHGs compared to 1990 levels. Milestones for this long-term goal were
set at a 25% reduction by 2020, 40% by 2030 and 60% by 2040. This communication was bolstered
by transport and energy efficiency frameworks to help facilitate these goals (European Commission,
2011).
At this point in time the COM identified in its roadmap the critical need for both a “sufficient
carbon price signal and long-term predictability” within the EU ETS in order to achieve the 2050
targets. This was the preliminary signal by the COM that review of the system may be necessary,
however, at this point in time it was only suggesting that existing EU ETS mechanisms should be
“revisited” as opposed to the creation of radical new ones (European Commission, 2011: 7). The
foremost suggestion made by the COM was for measures that include “recalibrating the ETS by
setting aside a corresponding number of allowances from the part to be auctioned during the period
2013 to 2020”, this would be imperative for improving the energy and cost efficiency of the EU ETS
(European Commission, 2011: 11). Nevertheless, at this point in time there were no suggestions to
initiate debate with stakeholders.
25
During the roadmap consultations, a frontline environmental non-governmental
organisation [ENGO] called E3G formed a coalition of local stakeholders who lobbied the European
Parliament in an attempt to adopt stricter emissions reduction targets as a part of the roadmap.
Despite the efforts of local stakeholders to amend the COMs proposal, the parliament rejected the
proposed 30% cut in emissions, settling for a less ambitious 25% (Interview 1, ENGO). Furthermore,
the Council of Ministers rejected the roadmap entirely after Poland’s environment minister vetoed
the proposal stating “we cannot agree to anything that would directly or indirectly allow for higher
emission-reduction goals in the near future” (Reuters, 2012). Ratcheting up GHG reduction targets
and shortening the timescale for achieving them could have damaged the Polish economy which
relies upon Coal for 90% of its electricity production (Reuters, 2012). Poland’s veto was an early
indication of intergovernmental bargaining in the run up to the reform process, since Poland halted
the commission from converting its goals from ‘soft law’ into a directive.
Notwithstanding this setback for the COM and local stakeholders, the COM kept the 2050
roadmap as an informal climate goal for member states to aspire towards achieving. Regardless of
this, the Paris agreement effectively solidified the gravity of these goals granting the EU greater
weight in employing the ‘shadow of hierarchy’. The agreement between 200 states was as created a
legally binding framework demanding that global temperatures must be capped at 2 degrees or ‘well
below’, effectively this runs with parallel ambitions to the goals of the 2050 roadmap (UNFCCC,
2015).
4.2 A milestones for the 2050 roadmap: the 2030 framework
Following the creation of the 2050 roadmap the COM began designing a framework for the
medium term to ensure that the 2050 targets could be met. To this end, “A policy framework for
climate and energy in the period from 2020 to 2030” was established as a directive in 2014 with
binding targets to - “provide regulatory certainty as early as possible for investors in low-carbon
technologies, to spur research, development and innovation and up-scaling and industrialisation of
supply chains for new technologies” (European Commission, 2014: 3). The 2030 framework builds
upon the goals of its predecessor [the 2020 framework] with the aim of using the EU ETS as the
prime instrument for achieving the following goals by 2030:
26
 At least 43% cut in EU ETS sector emissions compared to 2005
 At least a 27% increase in the share of renewables within EU energy consumption
 The framework sets a binding target at EU level to boost the share of renewables to at least
27% of EU energy consumption by 2030.
 A review of progress towards attaining this target in 2020
The 2030 framework feeds into the 2050 roadmap as a milestone with experimentalist feature
such as a mandate for recursive review of progress in 2020 in order to reach each and even increase
the binding targets [from 27% to 30%]. The establishment of binding targets has helped to reaffirm
the importance of meeting the EUs long-term goals, furthermore they heighten the need for an
effective long-term reform of the EU ETS, something that the framework stressed as a necessity for
achieving any targets (European Commission, 2014). However, despite this small victory by the COM,
the 27% binding target is only applicable at the EU level, agreed upon as a compromise between
climate mitigation leaders and laggards (Slominski, 2016). IGB has created a two-track Europe in
which incumbent states are afforded leeway to fall behind more progressive states (Interview 1,
ENGO).
4.3 The carbon market crisis: EUA surplus imbalance
The 2008 global financial crisis rapidly altered the price of EUAs as discussed [see section 1.3],
arguably it was the most dominant factor in the price collapse (Grosjean, et al., 2014) (Koch, et al.,
2014) (Interview 3, coal trade association) (Interview 5, expert). Between 2008 and 2011, 8171
million allowances were pumped into the EU ETS when it had been estimated that only 7765 million
tonnes CO2 equivalent were required. By 2012 the surplus had stacked up to 955 million EUAs,
meanwhile the supply of allowances was mandated to continue at a period when demand had hit at
an all-time low [due to the financial crisis], this shattered the price of EUAs [see below] (European
Commission, 2012).
27
[Figure 1: Timescale of EUA price drop (European Commission, 2012: 5)]
By 2020, it was forecast that the surplus of EUAs would have built up to approximately 2
billion. This could only be corrected with structural reform since the regulatory provisions stipulated
that the supply must rise throughout phase 3 [2013-2020] to raise revenue towards research and
development for carbon capture storage, which would support the energy efficiency of the fossil fuel
sector (European Commission, 2012).
5. Short-term structural reform of the EU ETS: ‘Back-
loading’
This section provides the first of a two part analysis of the structural reform process. The central
focus is upon the development of “Commission Regulation EU No 176/2014” – the 'Back-loading'
amendment to Auctioning Regulation (European Commission, 2014). The aim of this empirical
chapter is to analyse actors’ influence upon the design of the amendment, the relative success of the
established outcome, and the direction in which the reform process headed next [towards the
creation of the MSR]. The following approaches have been used to reach this objective; interest-
group and intergovernmental bargaining, institutional path dependency, and recursive learning from
past failures and local stakeholders [EG]. Combinations of policy documents and interviews have
been used to trace the process of reform, pointing out key junctures in chronological order. Analysis
of these junctures has been provided along the way to construct a narrative for the conclusion.
28
5.1 Initiating preliminary deliberation of EU ETS structural reform
After the failure of the COM and local stakeholders to get approval of the 2050 roadmap, the ENGOs
turned their focus towards reform of the EU ETS in order to advance efforts in tackling climate
change within the EU. At this point in time the efforts of the COM in tackling climate change had
stagnated after the rejection of its roadmap. By focusing upon the EU ETS as opposed to the COMs
broader climate policies, frontline ENGO and environmental campaigner E3G gained large support
from the private sector in its new mission to lobby for reform of the system, which was largely failing
in the wake of the EUA surplus imbalance. One interviewee suggested that part of the reason for the
failure of the roadmap discussion to secure long-term goals was due to the hostility the coalition
faced from other private actors of lobbying of the parliament and MS by the Industrial actors. Many
of these corporations simply could not see any impacts on their business model of the 3050
roadmap due to the uncertainty surrounding the targets of the proposal. Instead, it was agreed that
targeting reform of the EU ETS would be more important. A new coalition of local stakeholders
named ‘Friends of the ETS’ was setup by E3G to lobby on this issue, consisting of energy sector giants
such as Shell, E-on and EWEA (Change Partnership, 2012) (Interview 1, ENGO).
Looking a step back in time, E3G investigated the COMs communication - "Analysis of
options to move beyond 20% greenhouse gas emission reductions and assessing the risk of carbon
leakage" [26/05/2010]. Inside this communication E3G identified a suggestion by the COM of a
possible option for reform of the EU ETS in order to improve functionality which involved -
“Recalibrating the ETS by ‘setting aside’ a share of the allowances planned for auction”; an early
reference to utilising the concept of ‘Back-loading’ (European Commission, 2010: 7). Theoretically
this entailed removing EUAs from the market at a faster rate to reduce the surplus and increase the
market price of allowances (European Commission, 2010). Despite the COM alluding to the notion
reform with suggested options back in May 2010, they failed to initiate debate with stakeholders
leaving the surplus crisis to continue (Interview 1, ENGO).
Having received the backing of ‘Friends of the ETS’, E3G begun to build a campaign to set
aside or remove EUAs from the market in order to cancel them in the future. At this point in time the
COM was “fundamentally weak and slow”, they were worried about creating a political upheaval
that could upset any party of stakeholders (Interview 1, ENGO). This statement alludes to traces of
IDP and IGB; essentially DG CLIMA was concerned with changing the structural operation of the EU
ETS since this would involve a fundamental change in the way allowances are bought, sold and
removed from the market. Recalibrating the ETS would be a critical market intervention, one that
29
was always likely to have been met with strong opposition from incumbent anti-reform actors [i.e.
Poland and Hungary] (Interview 1, ENGO) (Interview 2, energy trade association).
Under political pressure from ‘Friends of the ETS’ the Directorate-General Climate Action
[DG CLIMA] of the COM launched a review of the ‘auction time profile of the EU ETS’ in April 2012 in
order to analyse the imbalance between the supply and demand of allowances (European
Commission, 2012). After establishing the weaknesses of the EU ETS affecting the carbon market, DG
CLIMA finally launched a public discussion on the options for structural reform in its ‘Consultation on
review of the auction time profile for the EU ETS’. This was the first juncture in which local
stakeholders were formally invited to provide feedback on DG CLIMAs options for structural reform
[amendment to Regulation (EU) No 1031/2010 (Auctioning Regulation)]. The victory of Friends of the
ETS over the COM shows that interest-group bargaining played a foundational role in initiating
discussions of structural reform. This happened through the collective efforts of local stakeholders
do define mutual goals [improving price signals trough reform] and acting upon this agenda to
secure them (Interview 1, ENGO) (Interview 2, energy trade association).
Explicitly, the ‘Back-loading’ amendment was designed as a temporary solution to the EUA
imbalance, in this sense the market impact of the first reform was never going to be high. Implicitly,
the reform was pushed through by interest-groups including Friends of the ETS to “drive a very big
wedge through a political system” (Interview 1, ENGO). The intention of this as to send a political
message from local stakeholders to the COM to signal that reform was not only necessary, but also
winnable in the political process, despite the COMs fears of having its reforms rejected by the
council due to IGB (Interview 1, ENGO) (Interview 2, energy trade association).
Prior to this the COM had effectively been “boxed in” by opposition to reform by member
states and trade organisations arguing that because the EU was on target to achieve its 2020 goals,
there was no need to take further action. Poland and the coal industry in particular were the most
vocal actors articulating this opinion (Interview 1, ENGO) ) (Interview 2, energy trade association).
Opposition towards the ‘Back-loading’ amendment from the coal industry was particularly explicit-
“the market is meant to determine the price, if you change this it is not a market anymore, it is
almost a tax - you don’t just start changing it because the price doesn’t make you happy - you just
leave the market how it is” (Interview 3, coal trade association).
Thus, bargaining with the COM to initiate ‘Back-loading’ discussions was “priceless” in that it
helped “build confidence” in DG CLIMA, enabling them to progress on towards proposing radical
long-term structural reforms i.e. the MSR. As a result, the MSR was established quickly off the back
30
of the ‘Back-loading’ amendment; since DG CLIMA were now in a stronger position propose a follow
up reform having navigated around incumbent actors in to establish a short-term solution (Interview
1, ENGO).
5.2 Launching a stakeholder consultation on review of EUA auctioning –
presenting the option of ‘Back-loading’
After receiving heavy political pressure from Friends of the ETS, DG CLIMA drafted a future
amendment of the auctioning regulations; this would later be developed into the ‘Back-loading’
amendment. The COM set up a consultation on review of the auction time profile from 25/07/2012
to 16/10/2012 with the aim of compiling the views of local stakeholders and frontline experts in
order to cross-check its proposals and ensure transparency (DG CLIMA, 2012). Overall, 151 position
papers were submitted with Poland owning 27 of these [the highest portion of responses]. The views
expressed in this consultation not only shaped the COMs proposals, but have also become vocal in
the later stage of the reform process through lobbying [see section. 5.4].
During the consultation, key stakeholders from the energy and power sectors came out in
favour of short-term reforms to the EU ETS stating that without emergency action the system would
be at risk of being replaced by other policy instruments (EURELECTRIC, 2012) (Interview 4, expert).
This was an important signal being sent to DG CLIMA one of the largest market stakeholders;
EURELECTRIC who are a trade association representing the views of the electricity industry in 32
European countries who are striving to achieve the goals of the 2050 roadmap (EURELECTRIC, 2016).
Their position was compounded by that of E3G a leading campaigner for EU ETS reform who stated
that - “without intervention and subsequent structural reform, we foresee an end to EU-wide
decarbonisation policy and substantial internal market distortions as governments renationalise
climate policy” (E3G, 2012: 1).
Despite overall support for making amendments to the auction regulations, a number of
stakeholders rejected the principal of market reform altogether. EURACOAL in particular stated that
the proposals would “place new burdens on EU industry at a time when the economy is already
fragile” (EURACOAL, 2012: 1). As representatives of the Polish and Czech coal industries, EURACOAL
are engaged in lobbying parliamentarians and the COM in order to safeguard the economic interests
of its members (Interview 4, expert). Since Poland are reliant upon coal for 90% of their electricity
production EURACOAL are effectively a commercial voice for the Polish governments’ climate and
31
energy agenda. This gives each coal production company a powerful voice in lobbying with the
additional backing of their respective national government; reinforcing the bargaining power of coal
interest groups with the IGB of their member states.
The weight of each stakeholders’ views are not only important to DG CLIMA in designing its
proposals, but also during the latter political stages. This is where the interest-group bargaining of
local stakeholders impacts upon the European Parliament and Councils policymaking decisions as
the next section details.
5.3 The Co-Decision Procedure and 'Back-loading'
Once DG CLIMA had proposed its options for reform, ‘Back-loading’ was selected by stakeholders as
the favoured option by stakeholders. Ensuing this, the next stage was to present ‘Back-loading’ to
the European Parliament [EP] to amend the auction regulations. Initially, the reform was rejected
after the European Parliament voted against the amendment proposals in March 2013. The head of
the centre right European People’s Party, the largest party in the European Parliament, issued a very
rare instruction to all party members to vote against the establishment of ‘Back-loading’. Their
argument was that withdrawing EUAs from the market through this mechanism would create higher
energy prices; restricting growth and job creation which were key elements of the parties’ agenda
(European People's Party, 2013). This event displayed the influence of GB upon MEPs who were
“heavily captured” by emission intensive industries. Heavy industries were lobbying to protect their
future by attempting to delay the downward financial pressure created the EUA price hike of ‘Back-
loading’ (Interview 1, ENGO) (Interview 3, coal trade association).
Likewise, ENGOs continued lobbying parliamentarians after the initial rejection of ‘Back-
loading’ in a bid to break the political deadlock slowing down the reform process. ‘Back-loading’ was
put to vote again in April 2013 after ENGOs and experts stressed the importance of the urgent need
for an effective reform (Interview 1, ENGO) (Interview 4, expert). Whilst GB was beginning to
persuade MEPs of the importance of ‘Back-loading’, Germany remained undecided on the
amendment due to inward pressure from its own heavy industries, whilst Poland outright objected
to the reform at all institutional levels. This was preventing the reform process from continuing since
nothing could be agreed without the approval by a majority of the Council. Eventually, Germany
came out in support of the amendment alongside the UK, France, Italy, the Netherlands, Denmark,
Portugal, Finland, Slovenia, Slovakia, and Estonia who signed a joint statement in support of the
reform (Euractiv, 2013) (Davey, 2013). In this statement the Energy and Climate secretary of the UK
32
issued a rally calling for “both the Council and Parliament take the urgent steps necessary, working
constructively together, to come to a swift resolution of the backloading proposal by July of this year
at the latest” (Davey, 2013: 1).
Following the folding of the German government into support for reform which broke the
political deadlock, the European Parliament voted in favour of the 'Back-loading' amendment to
Auctioning Regulation by a narrow vote of 344 to 311 (Interview 1, ENGO). It is evident that GB
played an influential role in both sides of the political deadlock as incumbent actors lobbied key
parties and member states to veto the reforms whilst trade associations led by ENGOs persistently
battled to promote the necessity - in their view of ‘Back-loading’. IGB was also present since Poland
effectively instructed its MEPs to veto the reform followed by a bloc support from 12 member states
during the second reading by the council and parliament (Interview 4, expert).
What was most intriguing about this series of political development was the fact that the
'Back-loading' proposal had been thrust into a new round of voting in April 2013 with almost
identical institutional arrangements as its predecessor; which had been rejected by parliamentarians
in March 2013. As discussed, the reversal in the voting patterns of MEPs to ‘Back-loading’ can be
attributed to GB. However, the initial rejection of the amendment also stems from a severe lack of
technical understanding of 'Back-loading' by MEPs. Only Committee members and the Rapporteur
were assigned the time to analyse and interpret the ‘Back-loading’ proposals. Contrary to this,
ordinary MEPs were given only a single day in which to read and understand the proposal amongst a
hundred plus further proposals due for analysis and voting on the day. The complexity of the COMs
proposal and the time constraints of the voting process meant that the regular MEPs had “no
chance” of grasping the technicalities of the reform. This was particularly apparent given that
dedicated teams of carbon market analysts required an entire evening to interpret and understand
what was being proposed by DG CLIMA. Adding to the complexity of the issue, when deciding which
way to vote, ordinary MEPs were heavily reliant upon the position of Committee members or their
respective party leaders, who in turn were being pressured by actors lobbying them from all levels.
Thus, even those MEPs who may have had a basic understanding of how ‘Back-loading’ would
operate were not able to vote according to their views due to instructions issued to their political
voting blocs (Interview 4, expert).
After the initial rejection of the reform, supporters of ‘Back-loading’ continued to lobby the
rapporteurs in an attempt to convince them of their opinions. This successfully led to a new round of
voting producing a bizarre reversal of voting patterns whereby MEPs who previously rejected the
amendment were now voting in favour of a reform. The new text contained a statement proclaiming
33
that if you previously voted against the establishment of ‘Back-loading’, you now by default have
had your views withdrawn when voting in favour of the second ‘Back-loading’ proposal (Interview 4,
expert). Finally, on 25/04/ 2014 Commission Regulation EU No 176/2014 'Back-loading' amendment
to Auctioning Regulation was established as the short-term solution to EUA imbalance. As a result,
growth in the EUA surplus stabilized and continued to decline into 2014 as supply and demand of
allowances reduced (European Commission, 2015).
6. Long-term structural reform of the EU ETS: the
Market Stability Reserve
This section provides the second of a two part analysis of the structural reform process. The central
focus is the development of “Decision (EU) 2015/1814 of the European Parliament and of the
Council” – the Market Stability Reserve [MSR] amendment to the EU ETS (European Commission,
2015). The aim of this empirical chapter is to analyse actors’ influence upon the design of the
amendment using the following approaches; interest-group and intergovernmental bargaining,
institutional path dependency, and recursive learning from past failures and local stakeholders [EG].
This is of particular importance for the argument of this thesis, since the MSR is the final outcome of
the structural reform process from which progress within EU governance can be analysed and
assessed. Combinations of policy documents and interviews have been used to trace the process of
reform, pointing out key junctures in chronological order. Analysis of these junctures has been
provided along the way to construct a narrative for the conclusion.
6.1 Preliminary deliberation of strengthening the EU ETS
Despite the eventual political success of establishing ‘Back-loading’, the interest-group ‘Friends of
the ETS’ moved toward lobbying for more ambitious strengthening of the EU ETS. Their efforts were
later supported by the 12 member states who signed the statement in favour of structural reform in
2013 in which they stated “We now urge the Commission to bring forward, by the end of the year at
the latest, proposals to perform a proper structural reform of the EU ETS” (Davey, 2013: 1). This was
in agreement with views expressed by local stakeholder who stressed that ‘Back-loading’ was only
intended to be a short-term resolution to the EUA imbalance; therefore a long-term option needed
34
to be established. Political pressure in the form of GB and IGB effectively created a domino effect in
which ‘Back-loading’ opened up a new realm for discussion about further reforms. This juncture
indicated to a small extent that the COM was learning from its stagnant reaction to previous calls for
reform, whereby it failed to react to the EUA surplus imbalance on its own accord (Interview 1,
ENGO).To this end, the DG CLIMA elevated its efforts in developing long-term options for
strengthening the EU ETS after the ‘Back-loading’ amendment. These were eventually released as a
part of the 2012 Carbon Market Report (European Commission, 2012).
Parallel in timing to DG CLIMA, frontline experts [consultants /carbon market analysts]
ENGOs began investigating their own long-term concepts for reform. These varied between different
consultancies from quantity corridors that adjust the supply of EUAs [e.g. similar to the MSR
mechanism] to price corridors with set high and low EUA price boundaries. Each of these
mechanisms would in theory help to balance the supply of EUAs and stabilise the price at a higher
level. Following this conceptualization stage, each interest-group comprised of competing ENGOs
and trade associations begun to lobby DG CLIMA with proposals to promote the organizations
agenda (Interview 2, energy trade association) (Interview 1, ENGO) (Interview 4, expert).
Nevertheless, whilst interest-group bargaining was observable in the form of lobbying, the
impact of this may have been low on the initial designs that evolved into the MSR. In the opinion of
local stakeholders, as time proceeds in the pre-release phase of the proposal since, it becomes
particularly “difficult” to influence DG CLIMA since they are so “entrenched” in their position from
the moment the design process begins (Interview 2, energy trade association). Stakeholder attitudes
allude to signs of institutionally path dependency and IGB effecting DG CLIMA. In part, pertains from
the lack of control the COM has over their proposals once they are processed through co-decision.
The COM aims to produce an initial proposal that keeps within the middle of the political spectrum
to minimise deviation from the original designs when they are evaluated by the European
Parliament and Council (Interview 2, energy trade association) (Interview 1, ENGO).
From the standpoint of stakeholders, DG CLIMA behaves like this to maximise the control
they have over each proposal by reducing the potential for further amendments or rejection by the
European Parliament and Council. Throughout the co-decision procedure, the COM can only attempt
to influence MEPs such as the rapporteur or shadow rapporteur of the Environment, Public Health
and Food Safety Committee [ENVI] or the Industry, Energy and Research Committee [ITRE]
committee. During the co-decision procedure, the role of the commission is reduced to being the
“broker” between parties (Interview 4, expert).The downside of the COM operating in this manor to
maintain control is that reforms are likely to be less radical and ambitious due to the fear of further
35
deliberation between rival institutions, MEPs or member states. As a result, in an endeavour to keep
within the centre of the political spectrum, the COM produced a proposal for the ‘flexible auction
supply of allowances’ which one local stakeholder brandished as ‘half right and half useless’ due to
the late start date of 2021 (Interview 1, ENGO). It is evident that influence of IGB and GB upon the
European Parliament is dampening the reflexivity of the EC when accommodating the views of
frontline experts into their initial proposals.
Another reason attributable to this is the internal setup of DG CLIMA which can lead to
institutional path dependency. Directing the ‘B1. ETS Policy Development and Auctioning’ of DG
CLIMA is Peter Zapfel, who has been described by interviewees as an “absolutely key” figure in the
EU ETS architectural design and development (DG CLIMA, 2016) (Interview 2, energy trade
association) (Interview 3, coal trade association) (Interview 4, expert). Zapfel has worked for the
department since the inception of the system and has “inside out knowledge” of the politics that
encompass its development (Interview 2, energy trade association). What is significant about Zapfel
is that he works in tangent with key local stakeholder such as carbon market analysts and influential
trade accusations throughout the design and amendment stages of the reform process. This gives
DG CLIMA a chance to receive frontline feedback on their progress (Interview 2, energy trade
association) (Interview 3, coal trade association).
Whilst some organisations have to lobby the COM to make their view heard, local
stakeholders from the energy market enjoy strong dialogue with DG CLIMA and are offered the
opportunity to present their options as due to their integral role with carbon and energy markets
(Interview 3, coal trade association). However, for carbon market experts it is a different story;
despite the rigorous efforts of DG CLIMA to work openly and transparently with them, engaging with
the COM has been depicted as a “one way road” (Interview 4, expert). Essentially, DG CLIMA seeks
to collate the informed opinions of experts on potential reform options in order to cross-check and
test their own preliminary proposals (Interview 5, expert) (Interview 4, expert). Furthermore,
experts will never receive a draft of the COMs work (Interview 4, expert). This is crossover between
features of EG and IPD, as DG CLIMA are overtly keen to include local stakeholders even at the
preliminary design and discussion phase to learn from their mistakes and test ideas via expert
opinion. Contrastingly, the COM are also treading carefully to maintain a vision of their own that
revolves around keeping a level control over proposals.
Furthermore, stakeholders have criticised the commission inferring that it is institutionally
path dependent in its fixation with improving price signals at the expense of long-term GHG
reduction and clean investment (Interview 4, expert) (Interview 3, coal trade association). One
36
potential cause is that DG CLIMA operates using full time economists to develop the EU ETS, but lack
a number of expert counterparts to relative to each economist. Expert counterparts specialising in
fields outside of the market economy could help provide a deeper understanding of technical issues
surrounding energy supply and the cost-efficiency of renewables versus clean technology [e.g.
carbon capture storage] (Interview 3, coal trade association). In effect, this can lead to a disconnect
between the COMs strategy for achieving its 2050 goals [to reduce GHG emissions long-term
through a stronger price signal] and the reality of reaching them; which stakeholders fear will
damage Eastern European economies in a bid to stimulate a low-carbon transition.
Some in the energy market go further to argue that affordable energy cannot even be
delivered in tangent with a green transition at this point in time due to “turf wars” between DG
CLIMA, DG Energy and DG Competition who have competing interests combined with a lack of inter-
departmental cooperation (Interview 2, energy trade association) (Interview 3, coal trade
association). This is particularly explicit in the interplay between the carbon pricing mechanisms of
DG CLIMA and renewable support mechanisms of DG ENERGY which is producing a lack of coherence
for investors due to the conflicting signals they send over investment in clean energy (Interview 2,
energy trade association).
To conclude this sub-section, there is good evidence to suggest from the standpoint of local
stakeholders and experts that COM is institutionally path dependant, but also captured to a smaller
extent by GB and IGB. DG CLIMA have also shown features of EG through their pro-active
interactions with local stakeholders and learning from previous failures to setup debate around
reform. However, as described by the interviewees the EC is still reluctant to adopt more radical
ideas proposed by stakeholders’ in the hope of winning its own and maintaining its own acceptance
as an actor. Crucially, this impacts hugely upon the design of subsequent reforms and the scale of
their ambition.
6.2 Stakeholder consultation on structural options to strengthen EU ETS –
presenting the MSR
After deliberation with stakeholders and lobbying by interest-groups, DG CLIMA brought forward its
report on the functioning of the carbon market titled ‘COM (2012) 652 final - The state of the
European carbon market in 2012'. This was a communication to the European Parliament and
Council to present preliminary options including “permanent withholding of the necessary amount of
37
allowances, for action with a view to adopting as soon as possible further appropriate structural
measures to strengthen the ETS during phase 3” (European Commission, 2012: 3). In total, six
options were presented as follows:
Option a: Increasing the EU reduction target to 30% in 2020
Option b: Retiring a number of allowances in phase 3
Option c: Early revision of the annual linear reduction factor
Option d: Extension of the scope of the EU ETS to other sectors
Option e: Use access to international credits
Option f: Discretionary price management mechanisms [e.g. a Market Stability Reserve]
The COM also stated - “Structural measures should be discussed and explored with stakeholders
without delay. These discussions can benefit from insights of the 2050 Low Carbon Economy and
Energy Roadmaps” (European Commission, 2012: 11). Crucially this shows the COM implementing
EG features within the reform process by formally inviting stakeholders to review its work.
Following this, the COM setup consultations between 07/12/2012 - 28/02/2013 so local
stakeholders could submit position papers reflecting their opinion of the six options in the carbon
market report. Much the same as the last consultation, stakeholders included Organisations
consisting of business associations; trade unions; representatives of civil society; such as non-
governmental organisations (NGOs); organisations representing other stakeholders groups; and
individual companies; Public authorities consisting of national and sub-national authorities; Citizens.
This is completed via an online questionnaire which one stakeholder described as being “extremely
infuriating” due to the intent of the questions asked, since the COM does not allow respondents to
provide a range of answers they would like to (Interview 2, energy trade association). Once again
this hints at traces of IPD since the COM has potentially narrowed the corridor within which
respondents can provide the full extent of their views. Nevertheless, the EC have showed reflexivity
in asking stakeholders not only to provide their opinion on the options at face value, but also their
expected impact upon each stakeholder and the prospect of them helping to achieve the 2050 goals
(European Commission, 2012).
Resultantly, energy-intensive industries claimed that there was too much concentration
upon the short-term options that were not clearly linked to the 2030 goals [the milestone before
2050]. This is yet another juncture that suggests the COM is consistently being sort-sighted in its
38
ambition to revive the EU ETS due to the risk of having a reform proposal rejected by the council due
to IGB from incumbent member states with carbon intensive economies. This view has been upheld
vocally by Poland, not only through lobbying, and IGB, but also through the stakeholder
consultations. Poland’s Ministry of Environment submitted a position paper rejecting all six options
presented by the COM based upon on the opinion that markets should not be adjusted:
“By forcing the investment in new technologies through price mechanism, the proposals
undermine the original reasons for implementing the system, which was supposed to be a cost-
effective mechanism for achieving reduction targets at international level. The EU ETS was designed
as a market mechanism, therefore interference in the market without a change to a long-term policy
and structural reforms will lead to a stronger dependence of the system on administrative and
political factors, as already the predictability of the market does not exist” (Polish Ministry of the
Environment, 2013).
Poland’s distain at of the concept of structural reform has been explicitly purveyed though
all levels of its stakeholders, from permanent representatives to the council, national ministries
during consultation and intensive lobbying by MEPs and interest-groups from heavy industries
[particularly coal]. IGB and GB by Polish actors at all levels have played a large role in slowing down
the political process that has produced the MSR (Interview 1, ENGO) (Interview 2, energy trade
association) (Interview 4, expert).
6.3 Expert meetings on EU ETS structural reform – refining the MSR
In conjunction with the stakeholder consultation, a full day meeting was held with experts on
02/10/2013 to discuss additional options for ‘Flexible auction supply of allowances’. This was a
crucial opportunity for DG CLIMA to engage with experts from carbon market analysis organisations,
industry, power generation, finance, research, market analysis, non-governmental organisations and
Member States. Importantly, one of the main outcomes of this engagement was the expression by
experts across the board that “regular review of the triggers is needed”, subsequently it was
proposed that these be carried out every 5 years of once per 8-year trading period. Effectively, this
would ensure that any flexible auction supply mechanism [i.e the MSR] would be regulated and
adjusted consistently to prevent past failures such as an EUA imbalance from reoccurring (European
Commission, 2013: 1). Significantly, the opinions of experts expressed in this meeting were directly
incorporated into the COMs final proposal and eventually the final decision:
Master Thesis - Reviving the European Union’s Emissions Trading System, Structural Reform of the EU ETS
Master Thesis - Reviving the European Union’s Emissions Trading System, Structural Reform of the EU ETS
Master Thesis - Reviving the European Union’s Emissions Trading System, Structural Reform of the EU ETS
Master Thesis - Reviving the European Union’s Emissions Trading System, Structural Reform of the EU ETS
Master Thesis - Reviving the European Union’s Emissions Trading System, Structural Reform of the EU ETS
Master Thesis - Reviving the European Union’s Emissions Trading System, Structural Reform of the EU ETS
Master Thesis - Reviving the European Union’s Emissions Trading System, Structural Reform of the EU ETS
Master Thesis - Reviving the European Union’s Emissions Trading System, Structural Reform of the EU ETS
Master Thesis - Reviving the European Union’s Emissions Trading System, Structural Reform of the EU ETS
Master Thesis - Reviving the European Union’s Emissions Trading System, Structural Reform of the EU ETS
Master Thesis - Reviving the European Union’s Emissions Trading System, Structural Reform of the EU ETS
Master Thesis - Reviving the European Union’s Emissions Trading System, Structural Reform of the EU ETS
Master Thesis - Reviving the European Union’s Emissions Trading System, Structural Reform of the EU ETS
Master Thesis - Reviving the European Union’s Emissions Trading System, Structural Reform of the EU ETS
Master Thesis - Reviving the European Union’s Emissions Trading System, Structural Reform of the EU ETS

Mais conteúdo relacionado

Destaque

Membran Ultrafiltrasi (UF)
Membran Ultrafiltrasi (UF)Membran Ultrafiltrasi (UF)
Membran Ultrafiltrasi (UF)Tirta Kalimaya
 
Ventas Que SI Venden
Ventas Que SI VendenVentas Que SI Venden
Ventas Que SI Vendenreskate
 
Promosi kesehatan
Promosi kesehatanPromosi kesehatan
Promosi kesehatanicaa__02
 
The Measurement of Tourism
The Measurement of TourismThe Measurement of Tourism
The Measurement of Tourismtellstptrisakti
 
Mumin's INT Credential
Mumin's INT  CredentialMumin's INT  Credential
Mumin's INT CredentialMumin's INT
 
Mumin'sINT Credential ENG
Mumin'sINT Credential ENGMumin'sINT Credential ENG
Mumin'sINT Credential ENGMumin's INT
 

Destaque (7)

Flame proof Flow Rate Indicator
Flame proof Flow Rate IndicatorFlame proof Flow Rate Indicator
Flame proof Flow Rate Indicator
 
Membran Ultrafiltrasi (UF)
Membran Ultrafiltrasi (UF)Membran Ultrafiltrasi (UF)
Membran Ultrafiltrasi (UF)
 
Ventas Que SI Venden
Ventas Que SI VendenVentas Que SI Venden
Ventas Que SI Venden
 
Promosi kesehatan
Promosi kesehatanPromosi kesehatan
Promosi kesehatan
 
The Measurement of Tourism
The Measurement of TourismThe Measurement of Tourism
The Measurement of Tourism
 
Mumin's INT Credential
Mumin's INT  CredentialMumin's INT  Credential
Mumin's INT Credential
 
Mumin'sINT Credential ENG
Mumin'sINT Credential ENGMumin'sINT Credential ENG
Mumin'sINT Credential ENG
 

Semelhante a Master Thesis - Reviving the European Union’s Emissions Trading System, Structural Reform of the EU ETS

The Cost of NonEurope in the Sharing Economy
The Cost of NonEurope in the Sharing EconomyThe Cost of NonEurope in the Sharing Economy
The Cost of NonEurope in the Sharing EconomyAlbert Canigueral
 
From Niche to Norm _ SEI
From Niche to Norm _ SEIFrom Niche to Norm _ SEI
From Niche to Norm _ SEIHanane Taidi
 
Moving towards a Circular Economy – Europe between Ambitions and Reality
Moving towards a Circular Economy – Europe between Ambitions and RealityMoving towards a Circular Economy – Europe between Ambitions and Reality
Moving towards a Circular Economy – Europe between Ambitions and RealityI W
 
Final report expert group foundations venture philanthropy social invest..
Final report expert group foundations venture philanthropy social invest.. Final report expert group foundations venture philanthropy social invest..
Final report expert group foundations venture philanthropy social invest.. Jorge Cortell
 
How to develop an adaptation city plan jrc1
How to develop an adaptation city plan jrc1How to develop an adaptation city plan jrc1
How to develop an adaptation city plan jrc1PatrickTanz
 
WS6b_BlueprintForSCP_Fedrigo
WS6b_BlueprintForSCP_FedrigoWS6b_BlueprintForSCP_Fedrigo
WS6b_BlueprintForSCP_Fedrigoactiontown
 
Green Energy- Green Business: New Financial and Policy Instruments for Sustai...
Green Energy- Green Business: New Financial and Policy Instruments for Sustai...Green Energy- Green Business: New Financial and Policy Instruments for Sustai...
Green Energy- Green Business: New Financial and Policy Instruments for Sustai...thinkingeurope2011
 
CCABBusinessinEuropefullreport
CCABBusinessinEuropefullreportCCABBusinessinEuropefullreport
CCABBusinessinEuropefullreportLaila Fernandez
 

Semelhante a Master Thesis - Reviving the European Union’s Emissions Trading System, Structural Reform of the EU ETS (20)

The Cost of NonEurope in the Sharing Economy
The Cost of NonEurope in the Sharing EconomyThe Cost of NonEurope in the Sharing Economy
The Cost of NonEurope in the Sharing Economy
 
Carbon finance
Carbon financeCarbon finance
Carbon finance
 
European Commission Report - From Niche to Norm
European Commission Report - From Niche to NormEuropean Commission Report - From Niche to Norm
European Commission Report - From Niche to Norm
 
From Niche to Norm _ SEI
From Niche to Norm _ SEIFrom Niche to Norm _ SEI
From Niche to Norm _ SEI
 
The blue book
The blue bookThe blue book
The blue book
 
The blue book
The blue bookThe blue book
The blue book
 
Moving towards a Circular Economy – Europe between Ambitions and Reality
Moving towards a Circular Economy – Europe between Ambitions and RealityMoving towards a Circular Economy – Europe between Ambitions and Reality
Moving towards a Circular Economy – Europe between Ambitions and Reality
 
Final report expert group foundations venture philanthropy social invest..
Final report expert group foundations venture philanthropy social invest.. Final report expert group foundations venture philanthropy social invest..
Final report expert group foundations venture philanthropy social invest..
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 387 - Institutional Harmonization and Its C...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 387 - Institutional Harmonization and Its C...CASE Network Studies and Analyses 387 - Institutional Harmonization and Its C...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 387 - Institutional Harmonization and Its C...
 
How to develop an adaptation city plan jrc1
How to develop an adaptation city plan jrc1How to develop an adaptation city plan jrc1
How to develop an adaptation city plan jrc1
 
WS6b_BlueprintForSCP_Fedrigo
WS6b_BlueprintForSCP_FedrigoWS6b_BlueprintForSCP_Fedrigo
WS6b_BlueprintForSCP_Fedrigo
 
Paraskevas call vp2010 007-en_
Paraskevas call vp2010 007-en_Paraskevas call vp2010 007-en_
Paraskevas call vp2010 007-en_
 
Paraskevas CALL FOR PROPOSALS VP/2010/007
Paraskevas CALL FOR PROPOSALS VP/2010/007Paraskevas CALL FOR PROPOSALS VP/2010/007
Paraskevas CALL FOR PROPOSALS VP/2010/007
 
Conclusions
ConclusionsConclusions
Conclusions
 
Climate Change and the Road to Copenhagen
Climate Change and the Road to CopenhagenClimate Change and the Road to Copenhagen
Climate Change and the Road to Copenhagen
 
Green Energy- Green Business: New Financial and Policy Instruments for Sustai...
Green Energy- Green Business: New Financial and Policy Instruments for Sustai...Green Energy- Green Business: New Financial and Policy Instruments for Sustai...
Green Energy- Green Business: New Financial and Policy Instruments for Sustai...
 
CASE Network Report 106 - The Costs of VAT: A Review of the Literature
CASE Network Report 106 - The Costs of VAT: A Review of the LiteratureCASE Network Report 106 - The Costs of VAT: A Review of the Literature
CASE Network Report 106 - The Costs of VAT: A Review of the Literature
 
Com 2015 215_en
Com 2015 215_enCom 2015 215_en
Com 2015 215_en
 
CCABBusinessinEuropefullreport
CCABBusinessinEuropefullreportCCABBusinessinEuropefullreport
CCABBusinessinEuropefullreport
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 310 - The Lisbon Strategy: a Tool for Econo...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 310 - The Lisbon Strategy: a Tool for Econo...CASE Network Studies and Analyses 310 - The Lisbon Strategy: a Tool for Econo...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 310 - The Lisbon Strategy: a Tool for Econo...
 

Master Thesis - Reviving the European Union’s Emissions Trading System, Structural Reform of the EU ETS

  • 1. 1 Reviving the European Union’s Emissions Trading System: Structural Reform of the EU ETS Master's Thesis MSc Political Science: International Relations Author: Miles Knight June 2016 First Reader and Thesis Supervisor: Prof Dr J.H. Zeitlin Second Reader: Dr. P. Schleifer
  • 2. 2 Acknowledgements The writer of this thesis would like to thank Prof Dr J.H. Zeitlin for supervising this project. Professor Zeitlin has provided excellent intellectual insight into the evolution of governance. Furthermore, he has also provided the inspiration for researching this topic by providing an outstanding overview of current political developments within European Union. I would also like to thank the Dr. P. Schleifer for taking giving up time to be the second reader of this thesis. Finally, I would like to thank and express my gratitude to all six interviewees who kindly gave up a great deal of their time and knowledge towards for the purpose of this research. List of acronyms COM – European Commission DG CLIMA – Directorate-General Climate Action [a subsidiary of the European Commission] EG – Experimentalist Governance ENGO – Environmental Non-Governmental Organisation ENVI – The European Parliament’s Environment, Public Health and Food Safety Committee of MEPs EU ETS – European Union Emissions Trading System EUA – EU Allowance [GHG permit] GB – Interest-Group Bargaining GHG – Green House Gases IGB – Intergovernmental Bargaining IPD – Institutional Path Dependency ITRE – The European Parliament’s Industry, Energy and Research Committee of MEPs MEP – Member of European Parliament MS – Member State MSR – Market Stability Reserve NFG – New Forms of Governance OMC – Open Method of Co-ordination
  • 3. 3 Contents 1. Introduction .................................................................................................................5 1.1 Climate change and the complexity of transnational mitigation .....................................................6 1.2 A transnational climate mitigation instrument for the European Union: Directive 96/61/EC - the EU ETS .....................................................................................................................................................7 1.3 Problem formulation & research questions .....................................................................................8 2. Theoretical framework & literature............................................................................. 11 2.1 New forms of governance in the EU [NFG].....................................................................................11 2.2 Experimentalist Governance [EG]...................................................................................................12 2.3 Approaches to political bargaining: interest-group bargaining [GB] and intergovernmental bargaining [IGB] ....................................................................................................................................14 2.4 Institutional path dependency [IPD]...............................................................................................16 2.6 Cap-and-trade systems, their strengths and weaknesses ..............................................................17 2.7 The Market Stability Reserve..........................................................................................................19 2.8 Section summary; a gap for new research......................................................................................20 3. Methodology.............................................................................................................. 21 3.1 Data.................................................................................................................................................22 4. The 2050 roadmap and the EUA surplus imbalance ..................................................... 23 4.1 Defining long-term goals for the EU ETS: the 2050 roadmap.........................................................24 4.2 A milestones for the 2050 roadmap: the 2030 framework ............................................................25 4.3 The carbon market crisis: EUA surplus imbalance..........................................................................26 5. Short-term structural reform of the EU ETS: ‘Back-loading’.......................................... 27 5.1 Initiating preliminary deliberation of EU ETS structural reform.....................................................28 5.2 Launching a stakeholder consultation on review of EUA auctioning – presenting the option of ‘Back-loading’........................................................................................................................................30 5.3 The Co-Decision Procedure and 'Back-loading' ..............................................................................31
  • 4. 4 6. Long-term structural reform of the EU ETS: the Market Stability Reserve .................... 33 6.1 Preliminary deliberation of strengthening the EU ETS ...................................................................33 6.2 Stakeholder consultation on structural options to strengthen EU ETS – presenting the MSR ......36 6.3 Expert meetings on EU ETS structural reform – refining the MSR .................................................38 6.4 The Co-Decision Procedure and the Market Stability Reserve.......................................................39 6.4.1 The impact of the European Council upon the final outcome.....................................................40 6.4.2 The impact of the European Parliament upon the final outcome...............................................41 7. The Market Stability Reserve and the road to 2050 ..................................................... 43 7.1 Driving down greenhouse gas emissions through decarbonisation...............................................45 8. Conclusions ................................................................................................................ 45 9. Bibliography ............................................................................................................... 48
  • 5. 5 1. Introduction Climate change is a global issue that requires transnational solutions. At the core of the issue is the anthropogenic emission of greenhouse gases which are driving force behind global warming. For decades the international community has attempted to resolve the issue through intergovernmental bargaining, nonetheless many of these attempts have fallen short of their targets [i.e. the Kyoto Protocol]. The European Union has taken it upon itself to set an example of how to abate greenhouse gas emissions in a transnational setting. Sitting at the heart of this ambitious plan is European Commission who has designed a long-term framework for transitioning towards becoming a low-carbon economy. Imperative to this vision is the goal to cut greenhouse gas emissions by 80- 95%% below 1990 levels, by the year 2050 (European Commission, 2011). Central to achieving this is the EU Emissions Trading System [EU ETS]; established in 2005 as the “cornerstone” of the EU’s GHG emission reduction strategy. This economic instrument utilises the concept of the market to find and set prices for CO2 allowances that are distributed by the Commission, either freely or at auction (EU Commission, 2013: 2) (Skjærseth & Wettestad, 2010). During each phase of the trading, allowances are removed from the market to reduce the ceiling, encouraging businesses within the system to make deeper investments in clean technology to avoid paying for expensive carbon permits. In practice, the market has failed in its most recent phase beginning in 2013. Surpluses of allowances were made available due to low demand for fossil fuels throughout the 2008 financial crisis, as a result, allowance prices have plummeted from 30 Euro/tCO2 to levels below 5 Euro/tCO2, and have failed to recover ever since (Schopp, et al. 2015). To resolve this chronic issue, extensive structural reforms have been requested by stakeholders through dialogue with the European Commission, and carbon market experts. Resultantly, the ‘Back-loading’ amendment to auction regulation was adopted as the short-term solution in 2014 to take immediate effect, followed by the Market Stability Reserve [MSR]; adopted as the long-term solution and due to operate indefinitely from in 2019. Whilst a long-term solution has been established, the reform process has been delayed blocking parties in the European Council, rejected proposals by the European Parliament and lobbying by numerous stakeholders. In an amongst the political deadlock local stakeholders including trade organisations, environmental NGOs and market experts have worked towards shaping the final outcome of reform alongside member state representatives. The final outcome [the MSR] is expected resolve the surplus imbalance, improve the systems functionality, and enable the EU ETS to remain as the EU’s first-best policy instrument for achieving the 2050 roadmap goals. With the hopes of the EU’s climate goals pinned on the MSR, this thesis aims to investigate is the ability of mechanism to revive the EU ETS. In order to do so this research
  • 6. 6 determines the extent to which interest-group and intergovernmental bargaining, institutional path dependency, or recursive learning from past failures and local stakeholders can explain the development and functionality of the final outcome. Subsequently, the argument presented in this paper is that features of experimentalism such as recursive learning from past failures and local stakeholders can help to create more robust reforms; reducing the negative aspects of uncertainty and political bargaining between member states, trade organisations and the European Commission. In theory, this promotes stability within the EU ETS creating a safer environment in which market actors can invest in low-carbon future. 1.1 Climate change and the complexity of transnational mitigation Anthropogenic emissions of green-house gases are now at the highest recorded level in human history. Scientists across the globe have observed and proven with ‘very high’ certainty that the warming of the climate system over the previous 60 years has been catalysed by anthropogenic emissions of GHGs. Carbon dioxide forms the largest concentration of all GHG gases in the atmosphere much of which is emitted through processes of combustion in engines in the generation of power. For this reason it is deducible that transport, power generation and the industrial sectors across the world form the crux of CO2 emissions, thus they have become the prime target for mitigation efforts by governments and civil society. The urgent need for mitigation stems from the agreed need to contain rising global temperatures within a 2 degree centigrade threshold. If this threshold is exceeded, the damage upon natural systems will be catastrophic and irreversible having severe knock on effects in the human environment that will ultimately claim more lives than it has already (IPCC, 2014). In many senses, proving through science that humankind is to blame for the current rise in global temperatures was comparatively straight forward; the step of generating global mitigation efforts is much harder. The mere notion of mitigation against climate change is one that has incurred great deliberation based upon historic, economic and philosophical arguments. The core of the dilemma is that no single state, company or section of society can or will bear the blame for the human races’ epic environmental blight. Effectively, this has led to a game of pass the GHG buck; the ramifications of this have meant that international climate negotiations have stalled numerous times until the late efforts of the COP21 meeting in Paris signalled a breakthrough. Meanwhile, industry and by extension its customers have escaped until recently from being held accountable for their role in inducing climate change. From and economic standpoint, the environmental impacts of
  • 7. 7 trading and consumption is an externality that has failed to be recognised and factored into the cost of goods, this has been referred to as “the greatest market failure the world has ever seen” (Stern, 2006: 1) (Callon, 2009). This is a situation that cannot persist if we wish to escape an impending tragedy of the commons catalysed by climate change (Hardin, 1968). 1.2 A transnational climate mitigation instrument for the European Union: Directive 96/61/EC - the EU ETS The EU produces 10% of global emissions, yet it has proudly striven to become the international leader in climate change mitigation efforts (European Commission, 2011). By 2005 the United Nations had hosted ten climate change conferences with almost no progress as a result. The Kyoto Protocol had been signed in 1997 but did not enter into effect until 2005 with the omission of two huge polluters; the US and China (Victor, 2011, chapter 7). However, in this same year, the EU launched its pilot phase of the world’s first emissions trading system, a ‘cap and trade’ system designed to reduce GHG emissions across Europe by harnessing the power of markets to trade emission allowances. The EU ETS became to be the “cornerstone” of the European Union’s efforts to reduce its own emissions ahead of the rest of the world, with the ambition of leading by example as the world’s first and largest carbon market (European Commission, 2013) (Skjærseth & Wettestad, 2009). The EU ETS works through the setting of a cap on the level of GHGs that can be emitted across industrial sectors with high carbon dioxide [CO2], nitrous oxide [N2O] and perfluorocarbons [PFC] emissions. These sectors include European energy and power, manufacturers, aviation operators within the Europe, and other high emitting business confederations. At present, the EU ETS spans 28 member states plus Iceland, Norway and Lichtenstein spanning 11,000 power installations and manufacturing plants. This means the system covers approximately 45% of the zones total emissions (European Commission, 2013). The cap is reduced on an annual basis in order to achieve a transition to a low-carbon economy. The goals for this have been set in the EU’s ‘2050 roadmap’ which demands an 80% minimum cut in greenhouse gas emissions compared to 1990 (European Commission, 2011). Before this target can be reached, a 40% reduction target must be met as a milestone laid out in the 2030 climate & energy framework (European Commission, 2014). Allowances for GHG emissions representing one tonne of CO2 each, can be bought and sold by companies in the carbon market
  • 8. 8 within the limits of the allowance cap. Theoretically, this provides flexibility for the companies involved, allowing them to choose when and how they cut their emissions in order to rely upon buying fewer allowances [increasing cost efficiency] (European Commission, 2013). The theory is that putting a price on carbon through cap-and-trade forces companies either to incur the cost of emitting GHGs either by paying for their emissions at a market rate, or by adopting clean technology to abate emissions; avoiding the need for more allowances. The higher the price of the EU Allowances [EUAs], the stronger the signal is to invest in clean, low-carbon technologies. Essentially, the system catalyses climate mitigation through the regulation of GHGs under a market setting (European Commission, 2014). 1.3 Problem formulation & research questions The EU ETS has been designated as the European Commission’s first-best policy for reducing GHG emissions. With this in mind it was designed to achieve the EUs commitment to the Kyoto Protocol between 2008 and 2012, with the ultimate goal of supporting the Union in achieving its 2020 climate and energy targets (European Commission, 2013). The prime goals of 2020 were to achieve a 20% cut in GHG emissions (from 1990 levels), to make 20% transition towards the use of renewables in the energy market, and to produce a 20% improvement in energy efficiency (European Commision, 2009). By and large the EU ETS is on track to do play its part in this with an 18% reduction in GHG emissions across the carbon market (European Commission, 2014). Beyond 2020, the future of the EU ETS as the most effective tool for achieving EU climate and energy policy is becoming clouded. The exogenous shock that was the 2008 financial crisis exposed new faults in the architecture and governance of the system, in the event of a crash in global markets that reduced economic growth. Due to this event, the price of fossil fuels collapsed as a result of a decrease in demand across the industrial and transport sectors (Grosjean, et al., 2014) (Koch, et al., 2014). Simultaneously, regulators continued to issue allowances creating a surplus in the market at a time when fossil fuels had become cheaper. With these two factors combined, it became economically efficient for EU ETS sectors to revert from clean energy technologies towards using old fossil fuel base technology. EUA prices had plummeted from €30 per tCO2 to levels below €5 per tCO2, facilitating a slow-down in the EUs transition towards adopting renewables (Schopp, et al., 2015).
  • 9. 9 Moving closer towards the year 2020, the EU has looked onwards to establish milestones for achieving the ‘2050 roadmap’ goals, intensifying and extending the EUs climate mitigation efforts further. The reformulated targets require at least 40% cuts in greenhouse gas emissions (from 1990 levels, a minimum 27% share for renewable energy, and at least 27% improvement in energy efficiency by 2030 (European Commission, 2014). However, after the carbon market report of 2012, it became clear that the EU ETS was not functioning well enough to achieve any meaningful climate goals set beyond 2020 (European Commission, 2012). Despite this, the EU ETS is still set to remain as the Commissions key tool for achieving the 2030 goals [and by extension the 2050 goals and the Paris agreement] prompting serious questions about the operation and governance of the system, even with structural reforms underway. With the decline in functionality of the EU ETS, the future of climate mitigation in the EU has become uncertain, a precarious problem if the EU wishes to continue as a ‘climate leader’ into the future to meet its own 2050 goals and map out a strategy for meeting the Paris agreement. Despite structural amendments in the form of ‘Back-loading’ [Commission Regulation No 176/2014], the surplus crisis is ongoing with EUA prices having hit a new 16 month low in February 2016 of €4.63 per tCO2 and are unlikely to recover significantly until the operation of the Market Stability Reserve [MSR] (European Commission, 2014) (EEX, 2016). The ‘Back-loading’ amendment to the EU ETS auctioning regulation is a short-term measure that reduces the volume of EUAs being auctioned in incremental steps; 400 million allowances in 2014, 300 million in 2015 and 200 million in 2016. These EUAs are withheld from being auctioned and have now been placed in the Market Stability Reserve. Effectively, this reduced the surplus of allowances on the market, driving up their price (European Commission, 2014). Whilst the ‘Back-loading’ was only short-term solution it has failed to perform as expected whilst the long-term solution to the market imbalance [the MSR] is due to start operation two years later than originally intended within the initial proposals. Meanwhile, stakeholders are still debating the credibility of the MSR mechanisms and its finer details. The latest development to the reform process is the launching of legal proceedings by Poland to sue the European Commission for making structural amendments within a trading period that it argues will damage operational and investment plans of Polish businesses (Republic of Poland, 2015). This series of recent events are in effect empirical evidence that underpin many of the critiques of ‘cap-and-trade’ systems as a cost-effective means of climate mitigation. Likewise, the structural reforms have carved a deeper rift between the actors committed to climate change mitigation, and those who are not; incumbent polluters (EurActiv, 2015). The problem presented in this thesis is a question of political bargaining and efficiency in resolving the carbon market’s
  • 10. 10 instability, and more importantly, in meeting the EUs 2050 climate goals. To this end, this research aims to ascertain whether the structural reforms past [‘Back-loading’] and present [MSR] can resolve the EUA surplus crisis and drive clean investment through an investigation of the political process that has eventually produced ‘Decision (EU) 2015/1814’ – the Market Stability Reserve (European Commission, 2015). In doing so, it is critical to ascertain which stakeholders have had the most influential role in the development of the reforms, and to match the views of various stakeholders with the final structural amendments that have been established. The purpose of this is to determine whether or not the European Commission has incorporated experimentalist features into its policymaking process through recursive learning from past failures and local stakeholders (Sabel & Zeitlin, 2008) (Sabel & Zeitlin, 2012). Arguably this is a mark of progress in developing a more stable and efficient system that will ensure the reduction of the EUs GHG emissions (Van Empel, 2014). Reflexive style governance with experimental features is vital for developing an ‘in vivo’ style market, one which relies heavily upon testing new institutional arrangements to improve functionality and the achieve climate mitigation goals that have been set (Callon, 2009). Furthermore, as discussed in the previous sections of this introduction, climate change mitigation is a complex and transnational issue that requires learning, the capacity problem-solve and above all, co-operation through deliberation. These are integral features of ‘experimentalism’ which this investigation aims to disclose in the governance of the EU ETS (Sabel & Zeitlin, 2008) (Sabel & Zeitlin, 2012). Thus, the experimentalist theoretical approach has been focused upon with the aim of establishing if it exists, and to what extent it could improve the governance of the EU ETS. Whilst preliminary research suggests that in theory, experimentalist features could prove to key for governing markets, it is also understood that other theoretical approaches may also explain the development of the reform process and the established outcomes. Policy reform of regulation within the EU is a complex process which requires the approval of stakeholders across multiple levels, which often have competing interests from each other and the European Commission. In light of this the institutional path dependency, intergovernmental and interest-group bargaining theoretical approaches will also be used to analyse the impact of competing stakeholders upon the established policy outcomes. Combining these approaches with experimentalism will help to divulge the evolutionary pattern of the reform process to determine how the EU ETS is being recovered and in what way this is shaped by the governance of the system.
  • 11. 11 To frame the problem that has been formulated, the research question of this thesis asks: What best explains the development of the structural reforms to the EU’s Emission Trading System: interest-group and intergovernmental bargaining, institutional path dependency, or recursive learning from local stakeholders and past failures? 2. Theoretical framework & literature This section will detail and analyse the theories and approaches that will underpin the argument throughout this thesis. Analyses of new forms of governance, experimentalism and classic theories of EU integration such as institutional path dependency and intergovernmental bargaining will provide the theoretical framework. Following this the theory behind cap-and-trade will be discussed in the context of the EU ETS so that the strengths and weaknesses of the system are exposed in light of the broader argument over the efficiency of cap-and-trade. Throughout, there will be references to key literature related to each section, but also exposure of gaps in research that this investigation intends to contribute towards closing. 2.1 New forms of governance in the EU [NFG] The crux of this research is an investigation into the approach of governance and decision-making that best explains the EU ETS structural reform process. Focus will in part be placed recursive learning from past failures and local stakeholders which can loosely be associated with the features of ‘new forms of governance’ [NFGs]. Scholarly discussion surrounding the development of NFGs arose from the establishment of the ‘open method of co-ordination’ [OMC] instrument in 2000 as a part of the Lisbon strategy. This framework induced economic cooperation between EU member states that were unwilling to yield policymaking powers to European institutions. The purpose of the design was to reduce political deadlock in the council through intergovernmental deliberation and co-evaluation of progress. Under the OMC member states must jointly search for and establish common goals, create instruments for measuring these goals, then benchmark performance through comparative studies and sharing of best practices. Essentially, this entails learning from each other’s progress through peer review. Standing at the heart of this process is the Commission who monitor progress whilst relying on ‘soft law’ to encourage compliance (Craig & De Búrca, 2011, chp. 6)
  • 12. 12 (Kohler-Koch & Rittberger, 2006) (European Commission, 2016). Since the development of the OMC the EUs approach to governance has evolved to cope with new transnational challenges across an array of areas including the environment. Research into NFGs has expanded to analyse this evolution. What defines NFGs and separates them from traditional hierarchical forms of governance is the faith they place in ‘soft law’. Soft laws are regulations or directives without sanctions for non- compliance; instead they coerce actors through mutual learning and socialization. In tougher situations they are enforced through the shadow of hierarchy; usually in the form of an implicit threat of public intervention such as legal action or tightening of regulations to settle the concern of non-compliance. Crucial to NFG is cooperation by higher actors units with local actors such as private organisations. Local actors are incorporated into the policy and decision-making process with the role of educating their retrospective member states on frontline issues, evaluating their proposals, or the policy goals of other high level actors. Whilst actors at all levels are included in this process of deliberation, the subsidiarity principal requires that member states hold the final vote on each legislative proposal which can lead to inter-governmental bargaining [see section 2.3] (Braun, 2009) (Craig & De Búrca, 2011, chp. 6) (Kohler-Koch & Rittberger, 2006). The conceptualisation of ‘new forms of governance’ provides a reasonable framework from which to approach the research questions of this thesis. At best it provides an interpretation of EU governance as shifting towards the reliance upon ‘soft law’, decentralised decision making including the input of actors at all levels, and the socialisation of institutional and governmental actors with local actors (Kohler-Koch & Rittberger, 2006). Cooperating with actors at multiple levels could produce a more balanced and effective reform that is functional and has popular support. However, new interpretations of EU policymaking have been established in the form of ‘experimentalist governance’ which could provide a more relevant framework from which the problem formulated in this thesis can be investigated. 2.2 Experimentalist Governance [EG] Sabel and Zeitlin have identified what they refer to as a new architecture of experimentalist governance [EG] in the EU, one that closely resembles the concept of ‘new forms of governance’. EG shares many of its principals with those noted in the previous section, in particular the emphasis upon the freedom of lower-level units to enact upon policy directives and regulations in a strategy of
  • 13. 13 their choosing. Autonomy of this scale is granted on the premise that lower-level or local actors must report back to each other under a peer review system, benchmarked against each other’s performance with the objective of meeting commonly agreed goals (Sabel & Zeitlin, 2008, 2012). Experimentalist governance, in the same way as NFGs, separates itself from ‘old’ hierarchical forms of governance through its unique theorisation of the way in which decision-making processes are beginning to evolve. The key difference is the integration of lower-level units into the socialization process. This refers to the practice of inviting local regulators, ministries, experts or consultants [i.e. carbon market analysts] at the forefront of their fields to analyse the progress of other actors and to provide state-of the art feedback to higher-level units [i.e. the European Commission]. Representatives of interest groups may also take part in committee style events in order to provide informal analysis, diversifying the deliberation process. This multi-level integration of actors enables local units to influence the final decisions of higher-level units (Sabel & Zeitlin, 2008, 2010) (Braun, 2009). Investigating networking between multiple levels has formed an essential part of this study since the European Commission must work to understand lower level stakeholders’ expertise and opinions. Without this, it would be unwise to govern a cap-and-trade system in which stakeholders can’t trust the market or the designers of the instrument. Whilst extensive networking is crucial, there are no set institutional arrangements in experimentalist architectures, so long as lower-level units receive autonomy to achieve the stated goals [i.e. the 2050 Roadmap; see section 3.2] in return for participation in the performance/peer review process. Perhaps the most important feature of EG for the argument of this investigation is its emphasis on the response of decision makers towards reducing the threat of uncertainty. In situations where uncertainty is persistent [i.e. carbon market instability and the unquantifiable threat of climate change], the decision-maker will work to understand the conditions that produce uncertainty and minimise them through the peer review process. This includes recursive learning from past failures, dynamic approaches to reform, and regular revision of goals, metrics and implementation methods to reflect what has been learnt through the peer review process. This process encourages actors to pursue the goals that have been set in a new environment which demands learning through difference or “joint exploration of possibilities” (Sabel & Zeitlin, 2012, pg.3). Ultimately, the EG approach to policymaking increases the capacity with which a community of actors can achieve goals, and react to reduce any uncertainty to depress any conflict between competing actor interests (Sabel & Zeitlin, 2012) (Verdun, 2012). Experimentalist governance is a relatively new concept that already has a flurry of empirical examples to underpin its theorisations. They traverse a wide range of policy fields from finance, to
  • 14. 14 food safety, forestry, chemicals, energy regulation and environmental protection (Zeitlin, 2015). With reference to the latter domain, perhaps the most outstanding empirical example is the Montreal Protocol. The Vienna Convention for the Protection of the Ozone Layer was heralded as one of the most successful international environmental protection agreements to date, to which strength is owed particularly to its experimentalist architecture. Amongst other features, the inclusion of a Technology and Economic Assessment Panel cooperating with a local industry based Technical Options Committees helped monitor and review progress in order to suggest amendments to the protocol. The success of this system became evident through the quick results that prevented atmospheric Ozone depletion through the combined efforts of 197 states (De Búrca, et al., 2014). Thus, in relation to this research it is important to understand the advantages of EG and what it can provide for environmental policy domains that face high levels of uncertainty [EU ETS Structural Reforms]. Preliminary research suggest that traces of EG has been incorporated into the EU ETS due to its close development by the Commission in partnership with local level units such as experts from consultancies, ENGOs and private companies (Braun, 2009). However, searching for EG architecture in correspondence with the success of policy outcomes could provide new evidence on the effectiveness of EG within environmental regulation. Here lies a gap in the literature to investigate the prominence of recursive learning from past failures and local stakeholders in the context of the EU’s first-best climate mitigation instrument, the EU ETS. 2.3 Approaches to political bargaining: interest-group bargaining [GB] and intergovernmental bargaining [IGB] The ultimate goal of this thesis is to determine the extent to which the structural reforms can resolve the EUA imbalance and help attain the 2050 climate and energy goals. Whilst the established outcome [the MSR] sets a benchmark from which to analyse the political decision-making process and assess the impact of varying stakeholders and institutional arrangements. In light of this, the European Commission employed extensive use of consultations with local stakeholders. Each of these stakeholders has its own agenda that may be different from that of the European Commission, Council or Parliament. Thus, lobbying is likely to be present as local actors bargain to a produce public good [a functional EU ETS] that generates a good return for the political and financial investment (Tollison, 2001). In order to understand the effects of local actors, the interest-group bargaining [GB] approach will be applied to provide a framework from which to analyse the behaviour of local stakeholders and the effect of their bargaining upon the final outcome of reform.
  • 15. 15 GB in many cases is likely to manifest in similar policy discussions as EG where local stakeholders are keen to bargain over their views throughout the deliberation process (Cutcher-Gershenfeld, 2014, chp. 6). Cutcher-Gershenfeld has compressed GB into 5 consecutive phases that detail the process of actors’ behaviour in negotiations, the most relevant of which are detailed here. During phase one; actors identify their own interests creating multiple plans for each whilst anticipating those of their opponents/counterparts. Phase three, actors produce initial statements defining their core interests, posing questions to other actors then co-operate to find common interests options. Phase four, actors search for mutual benefits across the range of issues. Following this, drafting of agreements begins to provide clarity over sides agreements and differences. The fifth and final phase, actors work to establish joint-implementation processes using mutually agreeable metrics for measuring both sides progress (Cutcher-Gershenfeld, 2014, chp. 6). To date, GB has not yet been used to analyse the structural reform process which provides a gap to investigate and present empirical findings on the impact of interest-group bargaining. However, research suggests that within the EU interest-group bargaining is influencing policy outcomes, particularly environmental directives. Generally, interest groups will mobilize and try to align themselves with national governments; they have a permanent seat in negotiations combined with voting power. Thus, if a government shares the views of an interest-group it is in that groups advantage to lobby through government officials. However, if a government does not have aligned views with the interest group, the group may seek to directly lobby the European Council or Parliament or do so through a wider European group i.e. a European trade association or local institutions with European connections (Callanan, 2011). Whilst GB is likely to be present, the co-decision procedure means the European Council have to agree with the European Parliament and any amendments they have made. In effect, the Council makes the final decision on whether or not an amendment is inscribed into law. Therefore the intergovernmental bargaining approach provides insight into the behaviour of member states such as Poland who have recently launched legal proceedings to sue the Commission due to its dissatisfaction with the early start date to the MSR [2019 as opposed to 2021] (Republic of Poland, 2015). In the context of the EU, intergovernmental bargaining theory is centred on member states and their ability to influence the policy outcome by pushing their agenda through the deliberation process. Essentially the agenda of each state reflects its domestic structure. States with similar preferences may align with each other if there are links between their policy goals or bargaining behaviour in the decision making procedure, but generally it is assumed that they will act through
  • 16. 16 rational choice to achieve what is best for their nation’s interests when negotiating EU legislation (Saam & Sumpter, 2009). A central assumption of this theory is that political infighting or socialization between member states can shape the final policy outcome. Member states are aware of the commissions influence in policy implementation and seek to alter this in order to restrict the Commission from commanding member states (Skjærseth & Wettestad, 2010). After reviewing the Commission’s proposals, state representatives will often strike a deal with the Commission to agree with their proposals on the basis that particular set decision-making procedures are abided by [e.g. a re- balancing the principal-agent relationship in future agreements] (Blom-Hansen & Brandsma, 2009) (Thatcher & Coen, 2008). The intergovernmental approach has been applied to EU ETS reform during previous phases. For example, Eastern European member states have been found to have significantly shaped the policy outcome of reform processes during the early pilot phases [2005- 2007 and 2008-2012]. However, there is a gap for using this approach to analyse the recent structural reforms that have produced the ‘Back-loading’ and MSR amendments, where there is lack of literature covering the new reforms (Skjærseth & Wettestad, 2010). 2.4 Institutional path dependency [IPD] The EU is constantly evolving; it is has not yet departed fully from ‘old’ hierarchical forms of governance. Furthermore, despite a movement towards NFGs and EG across EU policymaking, the European Commission remains a fundamental designer and coordinator of policy within the structure of the European Union. Thus, processes of reform may occur in path dependent ways as old institutional structures such as the European Commission and Council continue to mould or even restrict the policy strategies of new interest groups [e.g. local stakeholders and experts]. Using a historical institutionalist approach will allow for analysis of political outcomes via actors rule abiding or interest maximising behaviour as opposed to recursive learning through past failures and local stakeholders, features of EG (Thatcher & Coen, 2008) (Della Porta & Keating, 2008, chpater 7). With regard to the EU regulatory space, historical institutionalism has been cited as the most fitting approach for detailing the political layering that has occurred through the timescale of reforms and debates that have taken place. Thatcher and Coen argue that new institutions [rules of law/structural arrangements] tend to be an extension of the old with added enhancements since existing actors do not wish to concede power to new competing actors. Therefore they are likely to
  • 17. 17 be opposed to radical new institutions [e.g. structural reform options] that may alter the balance of power despite having the opportunity to solve past policy failures, this is often referred to as institutional path dependency [IDP] (Thatcher & Coen, 2008). 2.6 Cap-and-trade systems, their strengths and weaknesses This section builds upon the brief introduction to cap-and-trade found in section 1.2 by analysing the deep range of literature discussing the theory underpinning cap-and-trade, its strengths and weaknesses. Generally speaking, there are two prime instruments for encouraging climate mitigation; economic instruments [e.g. market systems such as cap-and-trade] or regulatory instruments [e.g. directives that demand the adoption of particular technologies or practices]. Theoretically, price based economic instruments such as cap-and-trade provide the incentive for companies to invest autonomously in clean technologies in order to avoid incurring economic costs. Conversely, regulatory instruments are intended to command control of companies’ emissions, performance or technology standards. This reduces the level of autonomy afforded to companies when working towards regulatory goals (O'Donnell, 2012)(Bergek & Berggren, 2014). Markets are increasingly being exploited as an economic instrument of choice. They have strong qualities that have produced rapid economic and social transitions across the world in a short period of history. On the down side, externalities such as the environment have been neglected for generations, exposing the weaknesses of their design. However, one solution to the shortfalls of markets is to harness the power of the market itself through a re-design of the socio-technical structures and regimes from which they have been produced (Callon, 2009) (Bergek & Berggren, 2014). Cap-and-trade is an example of this, first conceptualised in the 1970’s as solution to air pollution in the U.S. it was eventually tested in 1977 as a part of the Clean Air Act (EPA, 2016). Since their conception, cap-and-trade systems have been employed across the globe from the EU ETS to the California, Tokyo, Korean and Chinese Cap-and-Trade programs; all of which are market instruments to reduce GHG emissions and catalyse ecological modernisation. Now that the Paris agreement has been adopted at the COP21 negotiations, cap-and-trade systems are likely to be adopted in greater numbers across the globe in a bid to abate climate change (ICAP, 2016). The EU ETS is a pioneering experiment that takes a step beyond the rudimentary design of the clean air act or laboratory testing of markets. The EUs Emissions Trading System is an ‘in vivo’ experiment that has been founded and operated using a trial and error based learning system [learning through each new time phase]. Each phase of the system is monitored and reviewed in an
  • 18. 18 experimental approach with the aim of developing a system that increases in cost-efficiency and mitigation effectiveness. The very architecture of the EU ETS has been designed to be experimental with fixed review dates and temporary tests. Theoretically this approach should reduce uncertainty in the market through deliberation, learning and progressive results (Callon, 2009) (MacKenzie, 2009). Despite the experimental nature of the EU ETS, it is argued that the governance structures operating these systems are still “cruelly lacking” in leadership that needs to be critical, impartial and willing to be remain open to novel questions or views (Callon, 2009: 2). This is arguably more important than the features of a market itself; the way in which it is operated, governed and reformed. This argument supports the aims of this research to investigate recursive learning from past failures and local stakeholder engagement within the reforms. Across EU ETS sectors the Union has achieved an 18% reduction in GHG emissions relative to 1990 accompanied by a 13% rise in the share of renewables in 2012 (European Commission, 2014). Additionally, results show that the system has produced a significant increase in research and development in relation to projects for ETS sectors [Carbon Capture Storage being the biggest breakthrough]. Another advantage of the EU ETS is that having an internal market with a Union wide carbon price cuts out disparities that would occur between states due to individual national policies that could create a ‘two-track’ Europe that develops at different speeds (Egenhofer, et al., 2011). Overall, the most prominent success of the EU ETS has been in disseminating established clean technologies to reduce GHG emissions across industrial sectors without free permit allowances (Bergek & Berggren, 2014). Regardless of the strengths of cap-and-trade, it is by no means the ‘silver bullet’ in the battle against climate change. Theoretically, they have powerful benefits as discussed, but on the flip side they are accompanied by a series of weaknesses some of which are inherent and immutable. Sabel and Simon provide a good overview of the most prominent weakness, the first of which is the issue of GHG regulation. Emissions of GHGs can be measured effectively since it is known through scientific studies how many of each GHG compound can be expected to enter the atmosphere through which polluting activities. However, what cannot be calculated with high accuracy is the level of risk that each GHG will carry towards the environment due to the labyrinth of externalities caused by air pollution. In effect, this undermines the validity of carbon pricing and the setting of GHG reduction goals (Sabel & Simon, 2011) (IPCC, 2014). This is a particular problem if the EU wishes to achieve its 2050 goals since they can only serve as approximate targets as opposed to being definitive goals that can be measured and monitored accurately.
  • 19. 19 Secondly, market regulators must calculate the ancillary costs of GHG mitigation by second guessing the scale and damage that could be caused to the environment by substitute pollutants. These substitutes may be adopted by companies in place of the regulated ones [CO2, N2O and PFCs]. Empirical evidence of this could be witnessed in 2006. EUA prices crumpled as a result of regulators setting the aggregate emissions target too high after miscalculating the ‘business as usual’ emissions scenario. Resultantly the market price collapsed after regulators sent out the wrong price signals (Sabel & Simon, 2011). Thirdly, and perhaps most importantly, it remains unclear how potent a tool cap-and-trade systems can be at generating ecological modernisation or transfers of new clean technologies into the market. Due to the complex entanglement of renewable technology subsidies, fossil fuel taxes and emissions trading, it is extremely hard to separate the effects of cap-and-trade from those of other competing climate change abatement instruments (Skjærseth & Wettestad, 2010). There is little empirical evidence to suggest that market-instruments are the superior option when compared to environmental compliance instruments that demand clean technology transfers, in fact some evidence suggests they are inferior (Sabel & Simon, 2011) (Bergek & Berggren, 2014). Furthermore, it is argued that without the inclusion of the general public [individual consumption] from cap-and- trade systems, it is harder to transfer small scale local technologies to make additional improvements to abatement (Sabel & Simon, 2011). 2.7 The Market Stability Reserve Central to the second research question of this study is the market stability reserve. This automatic mechanism has been designed as a long-term solution to the structural imbalance of EUAs. Whilst this mechanism is yet to be deployed, there is already a wide body of literature discussing its strengths and weaknesses, all of which have critical effects upon the functionality of the EU ETS. The MSR is an automatic quantity-based mechanism that removes EUAs from the market based upon an upper threshold of 833 million. The MSR operates with a two year gap between the trigger events [e.g. an economic recession] and the build-up of EUAs to in circulation [creating a surplus imbalance], this gap allows for ex-ante assessment of the trigger event and an ex-post analysis of its implications upon the future of the market. When the upper threshold of EUAs has been reached, 12% of allowances in circulation are removed and placed into the reserve. The same process is mirrored when there is a shortage of EUAs in the market based upon a lower threshold of 400 million allowances (Richstein, et al., 2015).
  • 20. 20 The intended effect of the MSR is to reduce price volatility however opponents of the MSR have criticised some key assumptions made by the Commission in the design of the MSR. Hedging of allowances by market actors is a pivotal process in the market which the MSR attempts to pre-empt. However data on hedging does not have to be disclosed by companies’, therefore the MSR can only react to hedging based upon presumptions of market actors behaviour. In reality this could lead to a disconnect between the real hedging behaviour of companies’ versus the Commissions predictions. The end result of this could be a slow reaction by the MSR leaving EUA prices too low (Richstein, et al., 2015). It is also argued that the MSR will not increase the environmental effectiveness of the EU ETS, it will only prevent it from failing, reducing the uptake of carbon intensive activities (Acworth, 2014). Despite critiques of the reform, economists maintain that the MSR has the ability to enable the EU to achieve its 2050 climate goals providing other areas of the EU ETS are tweaked to support the MSR such as the linear reduction factor [LRF - the absolute decrease of EUAs, currently set at 1.74% per annum]. Increasing the LRF number to 2.55% would increase the effectiveness of the EU ETS, this was one of the proposed options for reform by the Commission that lost to the MSR during the consultation process (Hu, et al., 2015). Ultimately, the simplicity and transparency of the MSR will provide market actors with clarity over the short-term outlook of the carbon market (Acworth, 2014). 2.8 Section summary; a gap for new research To conclude, there is a breadth of research analysing the properties, strengths and weaknesses of cap-and-trade systems, including the EU ETS. Nevertheless, there is an acute lack of research investigating the institutional arrangements of the EU ETS moving into phase three and four [2013 and beyond]. Here lies a gap for analysing the governance of the system through the application of intergovernmental bargaining, institutional path dependency, interest-group bargaining and EG. Furthermore, within the literature there exists varying views of the MSR, its capacity to stabilize the market and reduce GHG emissions. Parallel to questioning the governance of the EU ETS, critiques of the MST open up questions over the policy outcomes of the structural reform process as well as the process of reform itself. In order to close the research gap, this thesis will provide a renewed overview of the EU ETS and the way in which it will continue to operate into the future in light of the 2050 climate and energy goals.
  • 21. 21 3. Methodology Outcome-oriented process -tracing is the preeminent method of choice in this study, used to track the timeline of developments throughout the EU ETS structural reforms to explain the outcome. Within-case analysis has helped to highlight and understand the causal relationships between the various actors. In particular it examines their preferences for particular policy amendments and the outcome of their interactions with other co-operative/rival actors on the final policy establishments by the Commission. Observations of political events recorded and published by the European Commission such as the release of reports, position papers and consultations have been matched up with changes to policy proposals and amendments to EU directives. This was carried out in chronological order to trace key actors impacts upon the structural reforms in order to determine which stakeholders have played the most significant role in altering the MSR design process. It also builds an understanding of how the final design of the reforms matched with actors preferences in the context of achieving the EUs 2050 goals. Ultimately this has helped determine which theoretical framework- intergovernmental and interest-group bargaining, institutional path dependency, or recursive learning from past failures and local stakeholders’ best describes the outcome of the structural reform process (Beach & Pedersen, 2016) (Tansey, 2007). Whilst political documents have formed the backbone of the study, tracking the timeline of political/technocratic movements or release of actor’s opinions, elite interview data has consolidated the information from this data through the following approaches. Firstly, they’ve been utilised to triangulate the connections between various policy documents, academic literature and the personal views of each interviewee to cross-check and reconstruct events throughout the reform process. Secondly, they have established in greater detail the attitudes and beliefs of different competing actors, enabling the research to highlight the motives of actors and the outcome of their influence. Thirdly, elite interview data has provided wider context to the actions and attitudes of large political groups or stakeholders, this is crucial given the sheer number involved in the reform process who could not be investigated (Tansey, 2007). This enables the researcher to make inferences about actors whose views may not otherwise be known, particularly in the case of the DG CLIMA who have explicitly declined to comment on any issues outside of what has already been published on their website. A purposive sampling approach has been used to select elite interviewees from a pre- defined list of actors; the DG CLIMA, ITRE, ENVI, permanent representatives of the European Council, carbon market experts and local stakeholders such as ENGOs and trade associations. This enables targeting of the most relevant actors who have remained close to the structural reform process or
  • 22. 22 hold a particularly great interest in the final amendments due to political or economic reasons. To achieve a representative sample of the actor population, interviewees have been chosen from all ends of the political spectrum based upon their public opinions of the MSR, proximity to the design of the MSR [carbon market experts] and availability for interviewing (Tansey, 2007). 3.1 Data The structural reform of the EU ETS has largely been a deliberative decision-making process led by the European Commission, for which key official policy documentation is published online by the Commission on its Climate Action website. This includes research, policy proposals and amendments, impact assessments and legal directives will be used to trace and analyse the Commissions learning and declarations. Some policy documentation may have remained undisclosed by the commission; these include initial designs for reform produced prior to expert consultation. Similar documentation types to those published by the commission have been used to interpret and detail the position and role of MEPs and Council members involved in the reforms. In conjunction with this, the Commission’s consultation process with EU ETS stakeholders requires that all organisations that have provided feedback upon each proposal have their position paper published online. These have been analysed to add depth to the study by detailing the viewpoint of local non-governmental and industrial actors. Expert interviews have been used to triangulate the knowledge gaps between the selection of documents, and to investigate the deliberation process between actors. The interviewees are high ranking representatives of organisations who have been involved at varying different levels and stages of the reform process from ENGOs, trade associations and carbon market consultancies employed as frontline ‘experts’ in the reform process. Unfortunately the European Commission declined a request for interview due to the ongoing political sensitivity of the reform process, as well as a number of MEPs who were contacted, including the rapporteur. As a result, the views expressed in this thesis largely represent those held by local stakeholders through their interactions with various European institutions, representatives or interest groups. Below is a list of the interviewees that provided data for this research, including their in text citations.
  • 23. 23 (Interview 1, ENGO) – CEO & Founding Director of the Change Partnership and former senior associate at E3G – role in the structural reform process: engaged in two public reform consultations on the ‘Back-loading’ and MSR amendments, and led a coalition of market stakeholders for reform of the EU ETS. (Interview 2, energy trade association) – Environment Consultant for an energy trade association – role in the structural reform process: engaged in two public reform consultations on the ‘Back- loading’ and MSR amendments, interviewees organisation has an ongoing working relationship with the its respective national government, the European Parliament and, EURELECTRC trade association. (Interview 3, coal trade association) – Public Affairs Manager for a coal and lignite trade association – role in the structural reform process: engaged in two public reform consultations on the ‘Back- loading’ and MSR amendments, also has an ongoing working relationship with DG CLIMA. (Interview 4, expert) – Founder and Head of Market Analysis at a carbon market intelligence organisation – role in the structural reform process: engaged in the ‘expert meeting on EU ETS structural reform: Introduction of a market stability’ on 25/06/2014, has an ongoing working relationship with DG CLIMA. (Interview 5, expert) – Head of Applied Research at a ‘new finance’ company – role in the structural reform process: engaged in the ‘expert meeting on EU ETS structural reform: Introduction of a market stability’ on 25/06/2014. (Interview 6, policy analyst) – Director of the Irish National Economic and Social Council – relation to the EU ETS: has researched and published an investigation into the performance of carbon pricing mechanism. 4. The 2050 roadmap and the EUA surplus imbalance This section outlines the origins of the structural reforms process that provide a crucial backdrop to the amendments of the EU ETS. Firstly, through analysis of the European Commission’s 2050 roadmap which has become the end-goal for the EU’s climate mitigation efforts, of which the EU ETS has been designated as the first-best instrument for achieving this. Secondly, it will briefly explain and analyse the cause and extent of the EUA surplus crisis that has led to a severe structural
  • 24. 24 imbalance of allowances. Ultimately this juncture prompted the need for emergency reform of the EU ETS in order to meet the goals of the 2050 roadmap. 4.1 Defining long-term goals for the EU ETS: the 2050 roadmap The first political juncture to spark movement towards structural reform began in the aftermath of the 2050 roadmap consultations. Amidst the EUA surplus crisis, and in the light of pledges at COP15, the European Commission [COM] began to design a long-term framework to help tackle the issue of transnational climate change mitigation [see section 1.1]. After consulting stakeholders at multiple levels, they produced a ‘Roadmap for moving to a competitive low carbon economy in 2050 - (08 Mar 2011)’ (European Commission, 2011). The 2050 roadmap was intended to provide the necessary cuts in GHG emissions for the EU to play its own part in keeping global temperatures below a fatal 2 degree rise (IPCC, 2014). Central to this communication was the emphasis upon transitioning towards becoming a competitive low-carbon economy. The approach is that the EU ETS [amongst other instruments] could drive investment in clean energy, improving energy efficiency to make a low-carbon transition across the Union, particularly in the power sector. The key target for emissions was set at a Union wide reduction of 80-95% of GHGs compared to 1990 levels. Milestones for this long-term goal were set at a 25% reduction by 2020, 40% by 2030 and 60% by 2040. This communication was bolstered by transport and energy efficiency frameworks to help facilitate these goals (European Commission, 2011). At this point in time the COM identified in its roadmap the critical need for both a “sufficient carbon price signal and long-term predictability” within the EU ETS in order to achieve the 2050 targets. This was the preliminary signal by the COM that review of the system may be necessary, however, at this point in time it was only suggesting that existing EU ETS mechanisms should be “revisited” as opposed to the creation of radical new ones (European Commission, 2011: 7). The foremost suggestion made by the COM was for measures that include “recalibrating the ETS by setting aside a corresponding number of allowances from the part to be auctioned during the period 2013 to 2020”, this would be imperative for improving the energy and cost efficiency of the EU ETS (European Commission, 2011: 11). Nevertheless, at this point in time there were no suggestions to initiate debate with stakeholders.
  • 25. 25 During the roadmap consultations, a frontline environmental non-governmental organisation [ENGO] called E3G formed a coalition of local stakeholders who lobbied the European Parliament in an attempt to adopt stricter emissions reduction targets as a part of the roadmap. Despite the efforts of local stakeholders to amend the COMs proposal, the parliament rejected the proposed 30% cut in emissions, settling for a less ambitious 25% (Interview 1, ENGO). Furthermore, the Council of Ministers rejected the roadmap entirely after Poland’s environment minister vetoed the proposal stating “we cannot agree to anything that would directly or indirectly allow for higher emission-reduction goals in the near future” (Reuters, 2012). Ratcheting up GHG reduction targets and shortening the timescale for achieving them could have damaged the Polish economy which relies upon Coal for 90% of its electricity production (Reuters, 2012). Poland’s veto was an early indication of intergovernmental bargaining in the run up to the reform process, since Poland halted the commission from converting its goals from ‘soft law’ into a directive. Notwithstanding this setback for the COM and local stakeholders, the COM kept the 2050 roadmap as an informal climate goal for member states to aspire towards achieving. Regardless of this, the Paris agreement effectively solidified the gravity of these goals granting the EU greater weight in employing the ‘shadow of hierarchy’. The agreement between 200 states was as created a legally binding framework demanding that global temperatures must be capped at 2 degrees or ‘well below’, effectively this runs with parallel ambitions to the goals of the 2050 roadmap (UNFCCC, 2015). 4.2 A milestones for the 2050 roadmap: the 2030 framework Following the creation of the 2050 roadmap the COM began designing a framework for the medium term to ensure that the 2050 targets could be met. To this end, “A policy framework for climate and energy in the period from 2020 to 2030” was established as a directive in 2014 with binding targets to - “provide regulatory certainty as early as possible for investors in low-carbon technologies, to spur research, development and innovation and up-scaling and industrialisation of supply chains for new technologies” (European Commission, 2014: 3). The 2030 framework builds upon the goals of its predecessor [the 2020 framework] with the aim of using the EU ETS as the prime instrument for achieving the following goals by 2030:
  • 26. 26  At least 43% cut in EU ETS sector emissions compared to 2005  At least a 27% increase in the share of renewables within EU energy consumption  The framework sets a binding target at EU level to boost the share of renewables to at least 27% of EU energy consumption by 2030.  A review of progress towards attaining this target in 2020 The 2030 framework feeds into the 2050 roadmap as a milestone with experimentalist feature such as a mandate for recursive review of progress in 2020 in order to reach each and even increase the binding targets [from 27% to 30%]. The establishment of binding targets has helped to reaffirm the importance of meeting the EUs long-term goals, furthermore they heighten the need for an effective long-term reform of the EU ETS, something that the framework stressed as a necessity for achieving any targets (European Commission, 2014). However, despite this small victory by the COM, the 27% binding target is only applicable at the EU level, agreed upon as a compromise between climate mitigation leaders and laggards (Slominski, 2016). IGB has created a two-track Europe in which incumbent states are afforded leeway to fall behind more progressive states (Interview 1, ENGO). 4.3 The carbon market crisis: EUA surplus imbalance The 2008 global financial crisis rapidly altered the price of EUAs as discussed [see section 1.3], arguably it was the most dominant factor in the price collapse (Grosjean, et al., 2014) (Koch, et al., 2014) (Interview 3, coal trade association) (Interview 5, expert). Between 2008 and 2011, 8171 million allowances were pumped into the EU ETS when it had been estimated that only 7765 million tonnes CO2 equivalent were required. By 2012 the surplus had stacked up to 955 million EUAs, meanwhile the supply of allowances was mandated to continue at a period when demand had hit at an all-time low [due to the financial crisis], this shattered the price of EUAs [see below] (European Commission, 2012).
  • 27. 27 [Figure 1: Timescale of EUA price drop (European Commission, 2012: 5)] By 2020, it was forecast that the surplus of EUAs would have built up to approximately 2 billion. This could only be corrected with structural reform since the regulatory provisions stipulated that the supply must rise throughout phase 3 [2013-2020] to raise revenue towards research and development for carbon capture storage, which would support the energy efficiency of the fossil fuel sector (European Commission, 2012). 5. Short-term structural reform of the EU ETS: ‘Back- loading’ This section provides the first of a two part analysis of the structural reform process. The central focus is upon the development of “Commission Regulation EU No 176/2014” – the 'Back-loading' amendment to Auctioning Regulation (European Commission, 2014). The aim of this empirical chapter is to analyse actors’ influence upon the design of the amendment, the relative success of the established outcome, and the direction in which the reform process headed next [towards the creation of the MSR]. The following approaches have been used to reach this objective; interest- group and intergovernmental bargaining, institutional path dependency, and recursive learning from past failures and local stakeholders [EG]. Combinations of policy documents and interviews have been used to trace the process of reform, pointing out key junctures in chronological order. Analysis of these junctures has been provided along the way to construct a narrative for the conclusion.
  • 28. 28 5.1 Initiating preliminary deliberation of EU ETS structural reform After the failure of the COM and local stakeholders to get approval of the 2050 roadmap, the ENGOs turned their focus towards reform of the EU ETS in order to advance efforts in tackling climate change within the EU. At this point in time the efforts of the COM in tackling climate change had stagnated after the rejection of its roadmap. By focusing upon the EU ETS as opposed to the COMs broader climate policies, frontline ENGO and environmental campaigner E3G gained large support from the private sector in its new mission to lobby for reform of the system, which was largely failing in the wake of the EUA surplus imbalance. One interviewee suggested that part of the reason for the failure of the roadmap discussion to secure long-term goals was due to the hostility the coalition faced from other private actors of lobbying of the parliament and MS by the Industrial actors. Many of these corporations simply could not see any impacts on their business model of the 3050 roadmap due to the uncertainty surrounding the targets of the proposal. Instead, it was agreed that targeting reform of the EU ETS would be more important. A new coalition of local stakeholders named ‘Friends of the ETS’ was setup by E3G to lobby on this issue, consisting of energy sector giants such as Shell, E-on and EWEA (Change Partnership, 2012) (Interview 1, ENGO). Looking a step back in time, E3G investigated the COMs communication - "Analysis of options to move beyond 20% greenhouse gas emission reductions and assessing the risk of carbon leakage" [26/05/2010]. Inside this communication E3G identified a suggestion by the COM of a possible option for reform of the EU ETS in order to improve functionality which involved - “Recalibrating the ETS by ‘setting aside’ a share of the allowances planned for auction”; an early reference to utilising the concept of ‘Back-loading’ (European Commission, 2010: 7). Theoretically this entailed removing EUAs from the market at a faster rate to reduce the surplus and increase the market price of allowances (European Commission, 2010). Despite the COM alluding to the notion reform with suggested options back in May 2010, they failed to initiate debate with stakeholders leaving the surplus crisis to continue (Interview 1, ENGO). Having received the backing of ‘Friends of the ETS’, E3G begun to build a campaign to set aside or remove EUAs from the market in order to cancel them in the future. At this point in time the COM was “fundamentally weak and slow”, they were worried about creating a political upheaval that could upset any party of stakeholders (Interview 1, ENGO). This statement alludes to traces of IDP and IGB; essentially DG CLIMA was concerned with changing the structural operation of the EU ETS since this would involve a fundamental change in the way allowances are bought, sold and removed from the market. Recalibrating the ETS would be a critical market intervention, one that
  • 29. 29 was always likely to have been met with strong opposition from incumbent anti-reform actors [i.e. Poland and Hungary] (Interview 1, ENGO) (Interview 2, energy trade association). Under political pressure from ‘Friends of the ETS’ the Directorate-General Climate Action [DG CLIMA] of the COM launched a review of the ‘auction time profile of the EU ETS’ in April 2012 in order to analyse the imbalance between the supply and demand of allowances (European Commission, 2012). After establishing the weaknesses of the EU ETS affecting the carbon market, DG CLIMA finally launched a public discussion on the options for structural reform in its ‘Consultation on review of the auction time profile for the EU ETS’. This was the first juncture in which local stakeholders were formally invited to provide feedback on DG CLIMAs options for structural reform [amendment to Regulation (EU) No 1031/2010 (Auctioning Regulation)]. The victory of Friends of the ETS over the COM shows that interest-group bargaining played a foundational role in initiating discussions of structural reform. This happened through the collective efforts of local stakeholders do define mutual goals [improving price signals trough reform] and acting upon this agenda to secure them (Interview 1, ENGO) (Interview 2, energy trade association). Explicitly, the ‘Back-loading’ amendment was designed as a temporary solution to the EUA imbalance, in this sense the market impact of the first reform was never going to be high. Implicitly, the reform was pushed through by interest-groups including Friends of the ETS to “drive a very big wedge through a political system” (Interview 1, ENGO). The intention of this as to send a political message from local stakeholders to the COM to signal that reform was not only necessary, but also winnable in the political process, despite the COMs fears of having its reforms rejected by the council due to IGB (Interview 1, ENGO) (Interview 2, energy trade association). Prior to this the COM had effectively been “boxed in” by opposition to reform by member states and trade organisations arguing that because the EU was on target to achieve its 2020 goals, there was no need to take further action. Poland and the coal industry in particular were the most vocal actors articulating this opinion (Interview 1, ENGO) ) (Interview 2, energy trade association). Opposition towards the ‘Back-loading’ amendment from the coal industry was particularly explicit- “the market is meant to determine the price, if you change this it is not a market anymore, it is almost a tax - you don’t just start changing it because the price doesn’t make you happy - you just leave the market how it is” (Interview 3, coal trade association). Thus, bargaining with the COM to initiate ‘Back-loading’ discussions was “priceless” in that it helped “build confidence” in DG CLIMA, enabling them to progress on towards proposing radical long-term structural reforms i.e. the MSR. As a result, the MSR was established quickly off the back
  • 30. 30 of the ‘Back-loading’ amendment; since DG CLIMA were now in a stronger position propose a follow up reform having navigated around incumbent actors in to establish a short-term solution (Interview 1, ENGO). 5.2 Launching a stakeholder consultation on review of EUA auctioning – presenting the option of ‘Back-loading’ After receiving heavy political pressure from Friends of the ETS, DG CLIMA drafted a future amendment of the auctioning regulations; this would later be developed into the ‘Back-loading’ amendment. The COM set up a consultation on review of the auction time profile from 25/07/2012 to 16/10/2012 with the aim of compiling the views of local stakeholders and frontline experts in order to cross-check its proposals and ensure transparency (DG CLIMA, 2012). Overall, 151 position papers were submitted with Poland owning 27 of these [the highest portion of responses]. The views expressed in this consultation not only shaped the COMs proposals, but have also become vocal in the later stage of the reform process through lobbying [see section. 5.4]. During the consultation, key stakeholders from the energy and power sectors came out in favour of short-term reforms to the EU ETS stating that without emergency action the system would be at risk of being replaced by other policy instruments (EURELECTRIC, 2012) (Interview 4, expert). This was an important signal being sent to DG CLIMA one of the largest market stakeholders; EURELECTRIC who are a trade association representing the views of the electricity industry in 32 European countries who are striving to achieve the goals of the 2050 roadmap (EURELECTRIC, 2016). Their position was compounded by that of E3G a leading campaigner for EU ETS reform who stated that - “without intervention and subsequent structural reform, we foresee an end to EU-wide decarbonisation policy and substantial internal market distortions as governments renationalise climate policy” (E3G, 2012: 1). Despite overall support for making amendments to the auction regulations, a number of stakeholders rejected the principal of market reform altogether. EURACOAL in particular stated that the proposals would “place new burdens on EU industry at a time when the economy is already fragile” (EURACOAL, 2012: 1). As representatives of the Polish and Czech coal industries, EURACOAL are engaged in lobbying parliamentarians and the COM in order to safeguard the economic interests of its members (Interview 4, expert). Since Poland are reliant upon coal for 90% of their electricity production EURACOAL are effectively a commercial voice for the Polish governments’ climate and
  • 31. 31 energy agenda. This gives each coal production company a powerful voice in lobbying with the additional backing of their respective national government; reinforcing the bargaining power of coal interest groups with the IGB of their member states. The weight of each stakeholders’ views are not only important to DG CLIMA in designing its proposals, but also during the latter political stages. This is where the interest-group bargaining of local stakeholders impacts upon the European Parliament and Councils policymaking decisions as the next section details. 5.3 The Co-Decision Procedure and 'Back-loading' Once DG CLIMA had proposed its options for reform, ‘Back-loading’ was selected by stakeholders as the favoured option by stakeholders. Ensuing this, the next stage was to present ‘Back-loading’ to the European Parliament [EP] to amend the auction regulations. Initially, the reform was rejected after the European Parliament voted against the amendment proposals in March 2013. The head of the centre right European People’s Party, the largest party in the European Parliament, issued a very rare instruction to all party members to vote against the establishment of ‘Back-loading’. Their argument was that withdrawing EUAs from the market through this mechanism would create higher energy prices; restricting growth and job creation which were key elements of the parties’ agenda (European People's Party, 2013). This event displayed the influence of GB upon MEPs who were “heavily captured” by emission intensive industries. Heavy industries were lobbying to protect their future by attempting to delay the downward financial pressure created the EUA price hike of ‘Back- loading’ (Interview 1, ENGO) (Interview 3, coal trade association). Likewise, ENGOs continued lobbying parliamentarians after the initial rejection of ‘Back- loading’ in a bid to break the political deadlock slowing down the reform process. ‘Back-loading’ was put to vote again in April 2013 after ENGOs and experts stressed the importance of the urgent need for an effective reform (Interview 1, ENGO) (Interview 4, expert). Whilst GB was beginning to persuade MEPs of the importance of ‘Back-loading’, Germany remained undecided on the amendment due to inward pressure from its own heavy industries, whilst Poland outright objected to the reform at all institutional levels. This was preventing the reform process from continuing since nothing could be agreed without the approval by a majority of the Council. Eventually, Germany came out in support of the amendment alongside the UK, France, Italy, the Netherlands, Denmark, Portugal, Finland, Slovenia, Slovakia, and Estonia who signed a joint statement in support of the reform (Euractiv, 2013) (Davey, 2013). In this statement the Energy and Climate secretary of the UK
  • 32. 32 issued a rally calling for “both the Council and Parliament take the urgent steps necessary, working constructively together, to come to a swift resolution of the backloading proposal by July of this year at the latest” (Davey, 2013: 1). Following the folding of the German government into support for reform which broke the political deadlock, the European Parliament voted in favour of the 'Back-loading' amendment to Auctioning Regulation by a narrow vote of 344 to 311 (Interview 1, ENGO). It is evident that GB played an influential role in both sides of the political deadlock as incumbent actors lobbied key parties and member states to veto the reforms whilst trade associations led by ENGOs persistently battled to promote the necessity - in their view of ‘Back-loading’. IGB was also present since Poland effectively instructed its MEPs to veto the reform followed by a bloc support from 12 member states during the second reading by the council and parliament (Interview 4, expert). What was most intriguing about this series of political development was the fact that the 'Back-loading' proposal had been thrust into a new round of voting in April 2013 with almost identical institutional arrangements as its predecessor; which had been rejected by parliamentarians in March 2013. As discussed, the reversal in the voting patterns of MEPs to ‘Back-loading’ can be attributed to GB. However, the initial rejection of the amendment also stems from a severe lack of technical understanding of 'Back-loading' by MEPs. Only Committee members and the Rapporteur were assigned the time to analyse and interpret the ‘Back-loading’ proposals. Contrary to this, ordinary MEPs were given only a single day in which to read and understand the proposal amongst a hundred plus further proposals due for analysis and voting on the day. The complexity of the COMs proposal and the time constraints of the voting process meant that the regular MEPs had “no chance” of grasping the technicalities of the reform. This was particularly apparent given that dedicated teams of carbon market analysts required an entire evening to interpret and understand what was being proposed by DG CLIMA. Adding to the complexity of the issue, when deciding which way to vote, ordinary MEPs were heavily reliant upon the position of Committee members or their respective party leaders, who in turn were being pressured by actors lobbying them from all levels. Thus, even those MEPs who may have had a basic understanding of how ‘Back-loading’ would operate were not able to vote according to their views due to instructions issued to their political voting blocs (Interview 4, expert). After the initial rejection of the reform, supporters of ‘Back-loading’ continued to lobby the rapporteurs in an attempt to convince them of their opinions. This successfully led to a new round of voting producing a bizarre reversal of voting patterns whereby MEPs who previously rejected the amendment were now voting in favour of a reform. The new text contained a statement proclaiming
  • 33. 33 that if you previously voted against the establishment of ‘Back-loading’, you now by default have had your views withdrawn when voting in favour of the second ‘Back-loading’ proposal (Interview 4, expert). Finally, on 25/04/ 2014 Commission Regulation EU No 176/2014 'Back-loading' amendment to Auctioning Regulation was established as the short-term solution to EUA imbalance. As a result, growth in the EUA surplus stabilized and continued to decline into 2014 as supply and demand of allowances reduced (European Commission, 2015). 6. Long-term structural reform of the EU ETS: the Market Stability Reserve This section provides the second of a two part analysis of the structural reform process. The central focus is the development of “Decision (EU) 2015/1814 of the European Parliament and of the Council” – the Market Stability Reserve [MSR] amendment to the EU ETS (European Commission, 2015). The aim of this empirical chapter is to analyse actors’ influence upon the design of the amendment using the following approaches; interest-group and intergovernmental bargaining, institutional path dependency, and recursive learning from past failures and local stakeholders [EG]. This is of particular importance for the argument of this thesis, since the MSR is the final outcome of the structural reform process from which progress within EU governance can be analysed and assessed. Combinations of policy documents and interviews have been used to trace the process of reform, pointing out key junctures in chronological order. Analysis of these junctures has been provided along the way to construct a narrative for the conclusion. 6.1 Preliminary deliberation of strengthening the EU ETS Despite the eventual political success of establishing ‘Back-loading’, the interest-group ‘Friends of the ETS’ moved toward lobbying for more ambitious strengthening of the EU ETS. Their efforts were later supported by the 12 member states who signed the statement in favour of structural reform in 2013 in which they stated “We now urge the Commission to bring forward, by the end of the year at the latest, proposals to perform a proper structural reform of the EU ETS” (Davey, 2013: 1). This was in agreement with views expressed by local stakeholder who stressed that ‘Back-loading’ was only intended to be a short-term resolution to the EUA imbalance; therefore a long-term option needed
  • 34. 34 to be established. Political pressure in the form of GB and IGB effectively created a domino effect in which ‘Back-loading’ opened up a new realm for discussion about further reforms. This juncture indicated to a small extent that the COM was learning from its stagnant reaction to previous calls for reform, whereby it failed to react to the EUA surplus imbalance on its own accord (Interview 1, ENGO).To this end, the DG CLIMA elevated its efforts in developing long-term options for strengthening the EU ETS after the ‘Back-loading’ amendment. These were eventually released as a part of the 2012 Carbon Market Report (European Commission, 2012). Parallel in timing to DG CLIMA, frontline experts [consultants /carbon market analysts] ENGOs began investigating their own long-term concepts for reform. These varied between different consultancies from quantity corridors that adjust the supply of EUAs [e.g. similar to the MSR mechanism] to price corridors with set high and low EUA price boundaries. Each of these mechanisms would in theory help to balance the supply of EUAs and stabilise the price at a higher level. Following this conceptualization stage, each interest-group comprised of competing ENGOs and trade associations begun to lobby DG CLIMA with proposals to promote the organizations agenda (Interview 2, energy trade association) (Interview 1, ENGO) (Interview 4, expert). Nevertheless, whilst interest-group bargaining was observable in the form of lobbying, the impact of this may have been low on the initial designs that evolved into the MSR. In the opinion of local stakeholders, as time proceeds in the pre-release phase of the proposal since, it becomes particularly “difficult” to influence DG CLIMA since they are so “entrenched” in their position from the moment the design process begins (Interview 2, energy trade association). Stakeholder attitudes allude to signs of institutionally path dependency and IGB effecting DG CLIMA. In part, pertains from the lack of control the COM has over their proposals once they are processed through co-decision. The COM aims to produce an initial proposal that keeps within the middle of the political spectrum to minimise deviation from the original designs when they are evaluated by the European Parliament and Council (Interview 2, energy trade association) (Interview 1, ENGO). From the standpoint of stakeholders, DG CLIMA behaves like this to maximise the control they have over each proposal by reducing the potential for further amendments or rejection by the European Parliament and Council. Throughout the co-decision procedure, the COM can only attempt to influence MEPs such as the rapporteur or shadow rapporteur of the Environment, Public Health and Food Safety Committee [ENVI] or the Industry, Energy and Research Committee [ITRE] committee. During the co-decision procedure, the role of the commission is reduced to being the “broker” between parties (Interview 4, expert).The downside of the COM operating in this manor to maintain control is that reforms are likely to be less radical and ambitious due to the fear of further
  • 35. 35 deliberation between rival institutions, MEPs or member states. As a result, in an endeavour to keep within the centre of the political spectrum, the COM produced a proposal for the ‘flexible auction supply of allowances’ which one local stakeholder brandished as ‘half right and half useless’ due to the late start date of 2021 (Interview 1, ENGO). It is evident that influence of IGB and GB upon the European Parliament is dampening the reflexivity of the EC when accommodating the views of frontline experts into their initial proposals. Another reason attributable to this is the internal setup of DG CLIMA which can lead to institutional path dependency. Directing the ‘B1. ETS Policy Development and Auctioning’ of DG CLIMA is Peter Zapfel, who has been described by interviewees as an “absolutely key” figure in the EU ETS architectural design and development (DG CLIMA, 2016) (Interview 2, energy trade association) (Interview 3, coal trade association) (Interview 4, expert). Zapfel has worked for the department since the inception of the system and has “inside out knowledge” of the politics that encompass its development (Interview 2, energy trade association). What is significant about Zapfel is that he works in tangent with key local stakeholder such as carbon market analysts and influential trade accusations throughout the design and amendment stages of the reform process. This gives DG CLIMA a chance to receive frontline feedback on their progress (Interview 2, energy trade association) (Interview 3, coal trade association). Whilst some organisations have to lobby the COM to make their view heard, local stakeholders from the energy market enjoy strong dialogue with DG CLIMA and are offered the opportunity to present their options as due to their integral role with carbon and energy markets (Interview 3, coal trade association). However, for carbon market experts it is a different story; despite the rigorous efforts of DG CLIMA to work openly and transparently with them, engaging with the COM has been depicted as a “one way road” (Interview 4, expert). Essentially, DG CLIMA seeks to collate the informed opinions of experts on potential reform options in order to cross-check and test their own preliminary proposals (Interview 5, expert) (Interview 4, expert). Furthermore, experts will never receive a draft of the COMs work (Interview 4, expert). This is crossover between features of EG and IPD, as DG CLIMA are overtly keen to include local stakeholders even at the preliminary design and discussion phase to learn from their mistakes and test ideas via expert opinion. Contrastingly, the COM are also treading carefully to maintain a vision of their own that revolves around keeping a level control over proposals. Furthermore, stakeholders have criticised the commission inferring that it is institutionally path dependent in its fixation with improving price signals at the expense of long-term GHG reduction and clean investment (Interview 4, expert) (Interview 3, coal trade association). One
  • 36. 36 potential cause is that DG CLIMA operates using full time economists to develop the EU ETS, but lack a number of expert counterparts to relative to each economist. Expert counterparts specialising in fields outside of the market economy could help provide a deeper understanding of technical issues surrounding energy supply and the cost-efficiency of renewables versus clean technology [e.g. carbon capture storage] (Interview 3, coal trade association). In effect, this can lead to a disconnect between the COMs strategy for achieving its 2050 goals [to reduce GHG emissions long-term through a stronger price signal] and the reality of reaching them; which stakeholders fear will damage Eastern European economies in a bid to stimulate a low-carbon transition. Some in the energy market go further to argue that affordable energy cannot even be delivered in tangent with a green transition at this point in time due to “turf wars” between DG CLIMA, DG Energy and DG Competition who have competing interests combined with a lack of inter- departmental cooperation (Interview 2, energy trade association) (Interview 3, coal trade association). This is particularly explicit in the interplay between the carbon pricing mechanisms of DG CLIMA and renewable support mechanisms of DG ENERGY which is producing a lack of coherence for investors due to the conflicting signals they send over investment in clean energy (Interview 2, energy trade association). To conclude this sub-section, there is good evidence to suggest from the standpoint of local stakeholders and experts that COM is institutionally path dependant, but also captured to a smaller extent by GB and IGB. DG CLIMA have also shown features of EG through their pro-active interactions with local stakeholders and learning from previous failures to setup debate around reform. However, as described by the interviewees the EC is still reluctant to adopt more radical ideas proposed by stakeholders’ in the hope of winning its own and maintaining its own acceptance as an actor. Crucially, this impacts hugely upon the design of subsequent reforms and the scale of their ambition. 6.2 Stakeholder consultation on structural options to strengthen EU ETS – presenting the MSR After deliberation with stakeholders and lobbying by interest-groups, DG CLIMA brought forward its report on the functioning of the carbon market titled ‘COM (2012) 652 final - The state of the European carbon market in 2012'. This was a communication to the European Parliament and Council to present preliminary options including “permanent withholding of the necessary amount of
  • 37. 37 allowances, for action with a view to adopting as soon as possible further appropriate structural measures to strengthen the ETS during phase 3” (European Commission, 2012: 3). In total, six options were presented as follows: Option a: Increasing the EU reduction target to 30% in 2020 Option b: Retiring a number of allowances in phase 3 Option c: Early revision of the annual linear reduction factor Option d: Extension of the scope of the EU ETS to other sectors Option e: Use access to international credits Option f: Discretionary price management mechanisms [e.g. a Market Stability Reserve] The COM also stated - “Structural measures should be discussed and explored with stakeholders without delay. These discussions can benefit from insights of the 2050 Low Carbon Economy and Energy Roadmaps” (European Commission, 2012: 11). Crucially this shows the COM implementing EG features within the reform process by formally inviting stakeholders to review its work. Following this, the COM setup consultations between 07/12/2012 - 28/02/2013 so local stakeholders could submit position papers reflecting their opinion of the six options in the carbon market report. Much the same as the last consultation, stakeholders included Organisations consisting of business associations; trade unions; representatives of civil society; such as non- governmental organisations (NGOs); organisations representing other stakeholders groups; and individual companies; Public authorities consisting of national and sub-national authorities; Citizens. This is completed via an online questionnaire which one stakeholder described as being “extremely infuriating” due to the intent of the questions asked, since the COM does not allow respondents to provide a range of answers they would like to (Interview 2, energy trade association). Once again this hints at traces of IPD since the COM has potentially narrowed the corridor within which respondents can provide the full extent of their views. Nevertheless, the EC have showed reflexivity in asking stakeholders not only to provide their opinion on the options at face value, but also their expected impact upon each stakeholder and the prospect of them helping to achieve the 2050 goals (European Commission, 2012). Resultantly, energy-intensive industries claimed that there was too much concentration upon the short-term options that were not clearly linked to the 2030 goals [the milestone before 2050]. This is yet another juncture that suggests the COM is consistently being sort-sighted in its
  • 38. 38 ambition to revive the EU ETS due to the risk of having a reform proposal rejected by the council due to IGB from incumbent member states with carbon intensive economies. This view has been upheld vocally by Poland, not only through lobbying, and IGB, but also through the stakeholder consultations. Poland’s Ministry of Environment submitted a position paper rejecting all six options presented by the COM based upon on the opinion that markets should not be adjusted: “By forcing the investment in new technologies through price mechanism, the proposals undermine the original reasons for implementing the system, which was supposed to be a cost- effective mechanism for achieving reduction targets at international level. The EU ETS was designed as a market mechanism, therefore interference in the market without a change to a long-term policy and structural reforms will lead to a stronger dependence of the system on administrative and political factors, as already the predictability of the market does not exist” (Polish Ministry of the Environment, 2013). Poland’s distain at of the concept of structural reform has been explicitly purveyed though all levels of its stakeholders, from permanent representatives to the council, national ministries during consultation and intensive lobbying by MEPs and interest-groups from heavy industries [particularly coal]. IGB and GB by Polish actors at all levels have played a large role in slowing down the political process that has produced the MSR (Interview 1, ENGO) (Interview 2, energy trade association) (Interview 4, expert). 6.3 Expert meetings on EU ETS structural reform – refining the MSR In conjunction with the stakeholder consultation, a full day meeting was held with experts on 02/10/2013 to discuss additional options for ‘Flexible auction supply of allowances’. This was a crucial opportunity for DG CLIMA to engage with experts from carbon market analysis organisations, industry, power generation, finance, research, market analysis, non-governmental organisations and Member States. Importantly, one of the main outcomes of this engagement was the expression by experts across the board that “regular review of the triggers is needed”, subsequently it was proposed that these be carried out every 5 years of once per 8-year trading period. Effectively, this would ensure that any flexible auction supply mechanism [i.e the MSR] would be regulated and adjusted consistently to prevent past failures such as an EUA imbalance from reoccurring (European Commission, 2013: 1). Significantly, the opinions of experts expressed in this meeting were directly incorporated into the COMs final proposal and eventually the final decision: