SlideShare uma empresa Scribd logo
1 de 139
Baixar para ler offline
Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet
            Some Lessons From the Past


                    Greg Taylor

                Oxford Internet Institute
                 University of Oxford
Economics



      The study of constrained choice.
Economics



      The study of constrained choice.
      Build mathematical models of decision makers’ behaviours.
Economics



      The study of constrained choice.
      Build mathematical models of decision makers’ behaviours.
            Typically gives us very sharp conclusions.
Economics



      The study of constrained choice.
      Build mathematical models of decision makers’ behaviours.
            Typically gives us very sharp conclusions.
            Suggests effects of policy changes—comparative statics.
Economics



      The study of constrained choice.
      Build mathematical models of decision makers’ behaviours.
            Typically gives us very sharp conclusions.
            Suggests effects of policy changes—comparative statics.
            But hard: the world is very complex, so we need assumptions.
Economics



      The study of constrained choice.
      Build mathematical models of decision makers’ behaviours.
            Typically gives us very sharp conclusions.
            Suggests effects of policy changes—comparative statics.
            But hard: the world is very complex, so we need assumptions.
            Thus another advantage of the mathematical approach:
            encourages transparency of assumptions.
Economics



      The study of constrained choice.
      Build mathematical models of decision makers’ behaviours.
            Typically gives us very sharp conclusions.
            Suggests effects of policy changes—comparative statics.
            But hard: the world is very complex, so we need assumptions.
            Thus another advantage of the mathematical approach:
            encourages transparency of assumptions.
      Let’s take a look at a textbook example of how some simple
      assumptions can be turned into a model.
Outline




   Price discrimination: from assumptions to policy statements



   Assumptions and applicability
Price discrimination




       Price discrimination is the practice of pricing such that
       different groups of consumers yield different price-cost
       margins for the firm.
A price discrimination example

      Imagine a monopolist firm that sells some products of varying
      quality.
A price discrimination example

      Imagine a monopolist firm that sells some products of varying
      quality.
          Assume that quality can be indexed by a number, q.
          Let q be continuous.
          Suppose that it costs C(q) to provide a product with quality q.
          Let C (q) > 0 (increasing costs), C (q) > 0 (convex costs),
          and C(0) = 0.
A price discrimination example

      Imagine a monopolist firm that sells some products of varying
      quality.
          Assume that quality can be indexed by a number, q.
          Let q be continuous.
          Suppose that it costs C(q) to provide a product with quality q.
          Let C (q) > 0 (increasing costs), C (q) > 0 (convex costs),
          and C(0) = 0.
      There are two types of customer: low (L), and high (H).
A price discrimination example

      Imagine a monopolist firm that sells some products of varying
      quality.
          Assume that quality can be indexed by a number, q.
          Let q be continuous.
          Suppose that it costs C(q) to provide a product with quality q.
          Let C (q) > 0 (increasing costs), C (q) > 0 (convex costs),
          and C(0) = 0.
      There are two types of customer: low (L), and high (H).
      A type i ∈ {L, H} consumer enjoys surplus

                               Ui = θi q − p.

      where p is the price to be paid to the firm, and θi is the
      consumer’s willingness to pay for a one unit increase in quality.
A price discrimination example

      Imagine a monopolist firm that sells some products of varying
      quality.
          Assume that quality can be indexed by a number, q.
          Let q be continuous.
          Suppose that it costs C(q) to provide a product with quality q.
          Let C (q) > 0 (increasing costs), C (q) > 0 (convex costs),
          and C(0) = 0.
      There are two types of customer: low (L), and high (H).
      A type i ∈ {L, H} consumer enjoys surplus

                               Ui = θi q − p.

      where p is the price to be paid to the firm, and θi is the
      consumer’s willingness to pay for a one unit increase in quality.
      Let θL < θH .
First order discrimination
       In a perfect world, the firm would know the type of consumer
       it is facing.
       It could then design a product/price combination for each
       type.
First order discrimination
       In a perfect world, the firm would know the type of consumer
       it is facing.
       It could then design a product/price combination for each
       type.
       i.e. Sell a ‘budget’ product with q = qL at price pL to L-type
       consumers, and a ‘luxury’ product with q = qH at price pH .
First order discrimination
       In a perfect world, the firm would know the type of consumer
       it is facing.
       It could then design a product/price combination for each
       type.
       i.e. Sell a ‘budget’ product with q = qL at price pL to L-type
       consumers, and a ‘luxury’ product with q = qH at price pH .
       The firm’s objective would then be to

                              max pi − C(qi )
                               qi ,pi
First order discrimination
       In a perfect world, the firm would know the type of consumer
       it is facing.
       It could then design a product/price combination for each
       type.
       i.e. Sell a ‘budget’ product with q = qL at price pL to L-type
       consumers, and a ‘luxury’ product with q = qH at price pH .
       The firm’s objective would then be to

                              max pi − C(qi )
                               qi ,pi

       subject to the constraint

                               θi qi − pi ≥ 0.
First order discrimination
       In a perfect world, the firm would know the type of consumer
       it is facing.
       It could then design a product/price combination for each
       type.
       i.e. Sell a ‘budget’ product with q = qL at price pL to L-type
       consumers, and a ‘luxury’ product with q = qH at price pH .
       The firm’s objective would then be to

                               max pi − C(qi )
                               qi ,pi

       subject to the constraint

                                θi qi − pi ≥ 0.


       This kind of behaviour is called first degree price
       discrimination.
First order discrimination

                max pi − C(qi ) s.t. θi qi − pi ≥ 0.
                 qi ,pi
First order discrimination

                   max pi − C(qi ) s.t. θi qi − pi ≥ 0.
                    qi ,pi


       In fact, since the firm knows θi , it can just set pi = θi qi .
First order discrimination

                   max pi − C(qi ) s.t. θi qi − pi ≥ 0.
                    qi ,pi


       In fact, since the firm knows θi , it can just set pi = θi qi .
       Substituting this into the maximisation problem gives

                               max θi qi − C(qi ).
                                 qi
First order discrimination

                   max pi − C(qi ) s.t. θi qi − pi ≥ 0.
                    qi ,pi


       In fact, since the firm knows θi , it can just set pi = θi qi .
       Substituting this into the maximisation problem gives

                               max θi qi − C(qi ).
                                 qi



       Increasing qi by one unit increases revenue by θi , and cost by
       C (qi ).
First order discrimination

                   max pi − C(qi ) s.t. θi qi − pi ≥ 0.
                    qi ,pi


       In fact, since the firm knows θi , it can just set pi = θi qi .
       Substituting this into the maximisation problem gives

                               max θi qi − C(qi ).
                                 qi



       Increasing qi by one unit increases revenue by θi , and cost by
       C (qi ).
       It is therefore profitable to increase quality if and only if
       θi > C (qi ).
First order discrimination

                   max pi − C(qi ) s.t. θi qi − pi ≥ 0.
                    qi ,pi


       In fact, since the firm knows θi , it can just set pi = θi qi .
       Substituting this into the maximisation problem gives

                               max θi qi − C(qi ).
                                 qi



       Increasing qi by one unit increases revenue by θi , and cost by
       C (qi ).
       It is therefore profitable to increase quality if and only if
       θi > C (qi ).
                   ∗
       So quality qi is produced where θi = C (qi ), i.e. where
       marginal cost of qi is equal to marginal willingness to pay for
       it.
What can we say about these qs?


      Firstly, by giving firms so much information about consumers,
      we have left the latter with no surplus.
What can we say about these qs?


      Firstly, by giving firms so much information about consumers,
      we have left the latter with no surplus.
      However, that θi = C (qi ) implies the chosen qualities are
      efficient!
What can we say about these qs?


      Firstly, by giving firms so much information about consumers,
      we have left the latter with no surplus.
      However, that θi = C (qi ) implies the chosen qualities are
      efficient!
          Social welfare given by consumer + firm welfare:

                    (θi qi − p) + (p − C(qi ))
What can we say about these qs?


      Firstly, by giving firms so much information about consumers,
      we have left the latter with no surplus.
      However, that θi = C (qi ) implies the chosen qualities are
      efficient!
          Social welfare given by consumer + firm welfare:

                    (θi qi − p) + (p − C(qi )) = θi qi − C(qi ).


          This is exactly what the firm is maximising!
What can we say about these qs?


      Firstly, by giving firms so much information about consumers,
      we have left the latter with no surplus.
      However, that θi = C (qi ) implies the chosen qualities are
      efficient!
          Social welfare given by consumer + firm welfare:

                    (θi qi − p) + (p − C(qi )) = θi qi − C(qi ).


          This is exactly what the firm is maximising!
      That θi = C (qi ) also implies that qL < qH , and hence
      pL < pH .
What can we say about these qs?


      Firstly, by giving firms so much information about consumers,
      we have left the latter with no surplus.
      However, that θi = C (qi ) implies the chosen qualities are
      efficient!
          Social welfare given by consumer + firm welfare:

                    (θi qi − p) + (p − C(qi )) = θi qi − C(qi ).


          This is exactly what the firm is maximising!
      That θi = C (qi ) also implies that qL < qH , and hence
      pL < pH .
Segmentation breakdown

      Now, firms typically cannot observe θi and so must depend on
      the consumer to buy the product designed for them.
Segmentation breakdown

      Now, firms typically cannot observe θi and so must depend on
      the consumer to buy the product designed for them.
      Therein lies a problem: if high consumers buy the high quality
      product, they get

                   θH qH − pH = θH qH − θH qH = 0,
Segmentation breakdown

      Now, firms typically cannot observe θi and so must depend on
      the consumer to buy the product designed for them.
      Therein lies a problem: if high consumers buy the high quality
      product, they get

                    θH qH − pH = θH qH − θH qH = 0,

      whereas if they buy the low quality product, they get

                      θ H qL − p L
Segmentation breakdown

      Now, firms typically cannot observe θi and so must depend on
      the consumer to buy the product designed for them.
      Therein lies a problem: if high consumers buy the high quality
      product, they get

                    θH qH − pH = θH qH − θH qH = 0,

      whereas if they buy the low quality product, they get

                      θH qL − pL > θL qL − pL
Segmentation breakdown

      Now, firms typically cannot observe θi and so must depend on
      the consumer to buy the product designed for them.
      Therein lies a problem: if high consumers buy the high quality
      product, they get

                    θH qH − pH = θH qH − θH qH = 0,

      whereas if they buy the low quality product, they get

                      θH qL − pL > θL qL − pL = 0.
Segmentation breakdown

      Now, firms typically cannot observe θi and so must depend on
      the consumer to buy the product designed for them.
      Therein lies a problem: if high consumers buy the high quality
      product, they get

                    θH qH − pH = θH qH − θH qH = 0,

      whereas if they buy the low quality product, they get

                      θH qL − pL > θL qL − pL = 0.


      Thus, all consumers will buy the budget product—this is
      called adverse selection.
Solution: mechanism design
      Question: What can the firm do about this?
Solution: mechanism design
      Question: What can the firm do about this?
      Answer: Change it’s maximisation problem.
Solution: mechanism design
      Question: What can the firm do about this?
      Answer: Change it’s maximisation problem.
      Suppose a consumer is of type L with probability α and of
      type H with probability (1 − α).
Solution: mechanism design
      Question: What can the firm do about this?
      Answer: Change it’s maximisation problem.
      Suppose a consumer is of type L with probability α and of
      type H with probability (1 − α). The new problem is then:
               max          α(pL − C(qL )) + (1 − α)(pH − C(qH ))
           qL ,pL ,qH ,pH
Solution: mechanism design
      Question: What can the firm do about this?
      Answer: Change it’s maximisation problem.
      Suppose a consumer is of type L with probability α and of
      type H with probability (1 − α). The new problem is then:
               max          α(pL − C(qL )) + (1 − α)(pH − C(qH ))
           qL ,pL ,qH ,pH

      subject to the constraint
                θH qH − pH ≥ θH qL − pL                (ICH)
                  θ L qL − p L ≥ θ H qH − p H           (ICL)
                θH qH − pH ≥ 0                         (IRH)
                  θL qL − pL ≥ 0                        (IRL)
Solution: mechanism design
      Question: What can the firm do about this?
      Answer: Change it’s maximisation problem.
      Suppose a consumer is of type L with probability α and of
      type H with probability (1 − α). The new problem is then:
               max          α(pL − C(qL )) + (1 − α)(pH − C(qH ))
           qL ,pL ,qH ,pH

      subject to the constraint
                θH qH − pH ≥ θH qL − pL                (ICH)
                  θ L qL − p L ≥ θ H qH − p H           (ICL)
                θH qH − pH ≥ 0                         (IRH)
                  θL qL − pL ≥ 0                        (IRL)



      Solving such a problem is known as second degree price
      discrimination.
IRL is ‘binding’

       Let’s begin by establishing that IRL holds with equality i.e.
       that θL qL − pL = 0.
           This means that home users are left with no surplus.
IRL is ‘binding’

       Let’s begin by establishing that IRL holds with equality i.e.
       that θL qL − pL = 0.
           This means that home users are left with no surplus.
       ICH says

                   θ H qH − p H ≥ θ H qL − p L
IRL is ‘binding’

       Let’s begin by establishing that IRL holds with equality i.e.
       that θL qL − pL = 0.
           This means that home users are left with no surplus.
       ICH says

                   θ H qH − p H ≥ θ H qL − p L ≥ θ L qL − p L
IRL is ‘binding’

       Let’s begin by establishing that IRL holds with equality i.e.
       that θL qL − pL = 0.
           This means that home users are left with no surplus.
       ICH says

                   θ H qH − p H ≥ θ H qL − p L ≥ θ L qL − p L


       Thus, if θL qL − pL > 0, then it must also be true that
       θH qH − pH > 0 so that neither IRL nor IRH bind.
IRL is ‘binding’

       Let’s begin by establishing that IRL holds with equality i.e.
       that θL qL − pL = 0.
           This means that home users are left with no surplus.
       ICH says

                   θ H qH − p H ≥ θ H qL − p L ≥ θ L qL − p L


       Thus, if θL qL − pL > 0, then it must also be true that
       θH qH − pH > 0 so that neither IRL nor IRH bind.
       But then the firm could increase both pL and pH without
       violating any condition.
IRL is ‘binding’

       Let’s begin by establishing that IRL holds with equality i.e.
       that θL qL − pL = 0.
           This means that home users are left with no surplus.
       ICH says

                   θ H qH − p H ≥ θ H qL − p L ≥ θ L qL − p L


       Thus, if θL qL − pL > 0, then it must also be true that
       θH qH − pH > 0 so that neither IRL nor IRH bind.
       But then the firm could increase both pL and pH without
       violating any condition.
       This implies that IRL must bind at the optimum.
ICH is ‘binding’

       We next show that ICH holds with equality i.e. that
       θ H qH − p H = θ H qL − p L .
           This means if the deal for the luxury product got any worse
           then H type consumers would switch to buying the budget
           product.
ICH is ‘binding’

       We next show that ICH holds with equality i.e. that
       θ H qH − p H = θ H qL − p L .
           This means if the deal for the luxury product got any worse
           then H type consumers would switch to buying the budget
           product.
       Suppose that this weren’t true:

                θH qH − pH > θH qL − pL
ICH is ‘binding’

       We next show that ICH holds with equality i.e. that
       θ H qH − p H = θ H qL − p L .
           This means if the deal for the luxury product got any worse
           then H type consumers would switch to buying the budget
           product.
       Suppose that this weren’t true:

                θH qH − pH > θH qL − pL ≥ θL qL − pL
ICH is ‘binding’

       We next show that ICH holds with equality i.e. that
       θ H qH − p H = θ H qL − p L .
           This means if the deal for the luxury product got any worse
           then H type consumers would switch to buying the budget
           product.
       Suppose that this weren’t true:

                θH qH − pH > θH qL − pL ≥ θL qL − pL = 0
ICH is ‘binding’

       We next show that ICH holds with equality i.e. that
       θ H qH − p H = θ H qL − p L .
           This means if the deal for the luxury product got any worse
           then H type consumers would switch to buying the budget
           product.
       Suppose that this weren’t true:

                θH qH − pH > θH qL − pL ≥ θL qL − pL = 0


       Thus, if ICH does not bind then neither does IRH.
ICH is ‘binding’

       We next show that ICH holds with equality i.e. that
       θ H qH − p H = θ H qL − p L .
           This means if the deal for the luxury product got any worse
           then H type consumers would switch to buying the budget
           product.
       Suppose that this weren’t true:

                θH qH − pH > θH qL − pL ≥ θL qL − pL = 0


       Thus, if ICH does not bind then neither does IRH.
       But then the firm could increase pH without violating any
       condition.
ICH is ‘binding’

       We next show that ICH holds with equality i.e. that
       θ H qH − p H = θ H qL − p L .
           This means if the deal for the luxury product got any worse
           then H type consumers would switch to buying the budget
           product.
       Suppose that this weren’t true:

                θH qH − pH > θH qL − pL ≥ θL qL − pL = 0


       Thus, if ICH does not bind then neither does IRH.
       But then the firm could increase pH without violating any
       condition.
       This implies that ICH must bind at the optimum.
Can neglect IRH and ICL



      That ICH binds implies θH qH − pH = θH qL − pL .
Can neglect IRH and ICL



      That ICH binds implies θH qH − pH = θH qL − pL .
      IRL implies θL qL − pL = 0.
Can neglect IRH and ICL



      That ICH binds implies θH qH − pH = θH qL − pL .
      IRL implies θL qL − pL = 0.
      Thus we have

              θH qH − pH = θH qL − pH > θL qL − pL = 0.
Can neglect IRH and ICL



      That ICH binds implies θH qH − pH = θH qL − pL .
      IRL implies θL qL − pL = 0.
      Thus we have

              θH qH − pH = θH qL − pH > θL qL − pL = 0.


      So IRH can be neglected.
Can neglect IRH and ICL



      That ICH binds implies θH qH − pH = θH qL − pL .
      IRL implies θL qL − pL = 0.
      Thus we have

               θH qH − pH = θH qL − pH > θL qL − pL = 0.


      So IRH can be neglected.
      This means that business customers get strictly positive utility.
Can neglect ICL




      It can also be shown that ICL does not bind.
      Briefly: since ICH binds θH (qH − qL ) = pH − pL .
Can neglect ICL




      It can also be shown that ICL does not bind.
      Briefly: since ICH binds θH (qH − qL ) = pH − pL .
      But ICL says (after rearranging) θL (qH − qL ) ≤ pH − pL .
Can neglect ICL




      It can also be shown that ICL does not bind.
      Briefly: since ICH binds θH (qH − qL ) = pH − pL .
      But ICL says (after rearranging) θL (qH − qL ) ≤ pH − pL .
      The inequality must be strict since θH > θL .
Can neglect ICL




      It can also be shown that ICL does not bind.
      Briefly: since ICH binds θH (qH − qL ) = pH − pL .
      But ICL says (after rearranging) θL (qH − qL ) ≤ pH − pL .
      The inequality must be strict since θH > θL .
      This means that the home bundle is strictly more attractive to
      home users than is the business edition.
qH is the set at the efficient level

                                                   ∗
       Now we will show that the chosen qH is qH —i.e. where
       C (qH ) = θH just like in the first order discrimination case.
           This implies that the quality offered to B-types is socially
           optimal.
qH is the set at the efficient level

                                                   ∗
       Now we will show that the chosen qH is qH —i.e. where
       C (qH ) = θH just like in the first order discrimination case.
           This implies that the quality offered to B-types is socially
           optimal.
       Suppose that the optimal qH has C (qH ) < θH .
qH is the set at the efficient level

                                                   ∗
       Now we will show that the chosen qH is qH —i.e. where
       C (qH ) = θH just like in the first order discrimination case.
           This implies that the quality offered to B-types is socially
           optimal.
       Suppose that the optimal qH has C (qH ) < θH .
           The firm could change qH to qH + ∆, and increase pH to
           pH + ∆θH without violating ICH, IRH, or ICL.
qH is the set at the efficient level

                                                   ∗
       Now we will show that the chosen qH is qH —i.e. where
       C (qH ) = θH just like in the first order discrimination case.
           This implies that the quality offered to B-types is socially
           optimal.
       Suppose that the optimal qH has C (qH ) < θH .
           The firm could change qH to qH + ∆, and increase pH to
           pH + ∆θH without violating ICH, IRH, or ICL.
           When ∆ is small, the change in the firm’s profits is
           approximately (1 − α)∆(θH − C (qH )) > 0.
qH is the set at the efficient level

                                                   ∗
       Now we will show that the chosen qH is qH —i.e. where
       C (qH ) = θH just like in the first order discrimination case.
           This implies that the quality offered to B-types is socially
           optimal.
       Suppose that the optimal qH has C (qH ) < θH .
           The firm could change qH to qH + ∆, and increase pH to
           pH + ∆θH without violating ICH, IRH, or ICL.
           When ∆ is small, the change in the firm’s profits is
           approximately (1 − α)∆(θH − C (qH )) > 0.
           Thus, original qH was not optimal.
qH is the set at the efficient level

                                                   ∗
       Now we will show that the chosen qH is qH —i.e. where
       C (qH ) = θH just like in the first order discrimination case.
           This implies that the quality offered to B-types is socially
           optimal.
       Suppose that the optimal qH has C (qH ) < θH .
           The firm could change qH to qH + ∆, and increase pH to
           pH + ∆θH without violating ICH, IRH, or ICL.
           When ∆ is small, the change in the firm’s profits is
           approximately (1 − α)∆(θH − C (qH )) > 0.
           Thus, original qH was not optimal.
       Similarly, if C (qH ) > θH : The firm can reduce qH to qH − ∆,
       provided it cuts its price for H by at least ∆θH .
qH is the set at the efficient level

                                                   ∗
       Now we will show that the chosen qH is qH —i.e. where
       C (qH ) = θH just like in the first order discrimination case.
           This implies that the quality offered to B-types is socially
           optimal.
       Suppose that the optimal qH has C (qH ) < θH .
           The firm could change qH to qH + ∆, and increase pH to
           pH + ∆θH without violating ICH, IRH, or ICL.
           When ∆ is small, the change in the firm’s profits is
           approximately (1 − α)∆(θH − C (qH )) > 0.
           Thus, original qH was not optimal.
       Similarly, if C (qH ) > θH : The firm can reduce qH to qH − ∆,
       provided it cuts its price for H by at least ∆θH .
           When ∆ is small, the change in the firm’s profits is
           approximately ∆(C (qH ) − θH ) > 0
Optimal prices




      Now we can set about characterising the optimal prices.
Optimal prices




      Now we can set about characterising the optimal prices.
      Since IRL binds, we know that pL = θL qL .
Optimal prices




      Now we can set about characterising the optimal prices.
      Since IRL binds, we know that pL = θL qL .
      Since ICH binds, we know that θH qH − pH = θH qL − pL , or
                                        ∗
      equivalently, that pH = pL + θH (qH − qL ).
Optimal prices




      Now we can set about characterising the optimal prices.
      Since IRL binds, we know that pL = θL qL .
      Since ICH binds, we know that θH qH − pH = θH qL − pL , or
                                        ∗
      equivalently, that pH = pL + θH (qH − qL ).
                                                        ∗
      Combining these two statements: pH = θL qL + θH (qH − qL ).
Firm’s objective
       The firm’s objective is

                max          α(pL − C(qL )) + (1 − α)(pH − C(qH )).
            qL ,pL ,qH ,pH
Firm’s objective
       The firm’s objective is

                 max          α(pL − C(qL )) + (1 − α)(pH − C(qH )).
             qL ,pL ,qH ,pH



       Substituting in the material we just derived (Note: since
              ∗
       qH = qH , we only need to worry about the choice of qL .):
                                                ∗             ∗
       max α(θL qL −C(qL ))+(1−α) [θL qL + θH (qH − qL ) − C(qH )] .
        qL
Firm’s objective
       The firm’s objective is

                 max          α(pL − C(qL )) + (1 − α)(pH − C(qH )).
             qL ,pL ,qH ,pH



       Substituting in the material we just derived (Note: since
              ∗
       qH = qH , we only need to worry about the choice of qL .):
                                                ∗             ∗
       max α(θL qL −C(qL ))+(1−α) [θL qL + θH (qH − qL ) − C(qH )] .
        qL



       We can easily calculate the qL that maximises this by
       differentiating:

                    α θL − C (qL ) + (1 − α) [θL − θH ] = 0
Firm’s objective
       The firm’s objective is

                 max          α(pL − C(qL )) + (1 − α)(pH − C(qH )).
             qL ,pL ,qH ,pH



       Substituting in the material we just derived (Note: since
              ∗
       qH = qH , we only need to worry about the choice of qL .):
                                                ∗             ∗
       max α(θL qL −C(qL ))+(1−α) [θL qL + θH (qH − qL ) − C(qH )] .
        qL



       We can easily calculate the qL that maximises this by
       differentiating:

                    α θL − C (qL ) + (1 − α) [θL − θH ] = 0


                                          1−α
       Rearranging: C (qL ) = θL −         α    [θH − θL ]
Firm’s objective
       The firm’s objective is

                 max          α(pL − C(qL )) + (1 − α)(pH − C(qH )).
             qL ,pL ,qH ,pH



       Substituting in the material we just derived (Note: since
              ∗
       qH = qH , we only need to worry about the choice of qL .):
                                                ∗             ∗
       max α(θL qL −C(qL ))+(1−α) [θL qL + θH (qH − qL ) − C(qH )] .
        qL



       We can easily calculate the qL that maximises this by
       differentiating:

                    α θL − C (qL ) + (1 − α) [θL − θH ] = 0


                                          1−α
       Rearranging: C (qL ) = θL −         α    [θH − θL ] < θL
Discussion of the model


      The name of the game is to separate clients into groups and
      milk each group for as much as possible.
Discussion of the model


      The name of the game is to separate clients into groups and
      milk each group for as much as possible.
      The monopolist can squeeze more profit from high value
      customers, who will pay more for a given increase in quality.
Discussion of the model


      The name of the game is to separate clients into groups and
      milk each group for as much as possible.
      The monopolist can squeeze more profit from high value
      customers, who will pay more for a given increase in quality.
      But they can’t squeeze too hard—otherwise high value
      consumers will just buy the cheap product.
Discussion of the model


      The name of the game is to separate clients into groups and
      milk each group for as much as possible.
      The monopolist can squeeze more profit from high value
      customers, who will pay more for a given increase in quality.
      But they can’t squeeze too hard—otherwise high value
      consumers will just buy the cheap product.
      Solution: deliberately degrade the usefulness of the budget
      product to ensure that high-value customers refuse to buy it.
Discussion of the model


      The name of the game is to separate clients into groups and
      milk each group for as much as possible.
      The monopolist can squeeze more profit from high value
      customers, who will pay more for a given increase in quality.
      But they can’t squeeze too hard—otherwise high value
      consumers will just buy the cheap product.
      Solution: deliberately degrade the usefulness of the budget
      product to ensure that high-value customers refuse to buy it.
      Then the firm can charge a high price for the premium
      product, without worrying about customers switching to
      cheaper versions.
Discussion of the model


      The name of the game is to separate clients into groups and
      milk each group for as much as possible.
      The monopolist can squeeze more profit from high value
      customers, who will pay more for a given increase in quality.
      But they can’t squeeze too hard—otherwise high value
      consumers will just buy the cheap product.
      Solution: deliberately degrade the usefulness of the budget
      product to ensure that high-value customers refuse to buy it.
      Then the firm can charge a high price for the premium
      product, without worrying about customers switching to
      cheaper versions.
Examples




       £2/kg   £2/kg   £10/kg   £18/kg
Examples




  It is not because of the few thousand francs which would have to
  be spent to put a roof over the third-class carriage or to upholster
  the third-class seats that some company or other has open
  carriages with wooden benches. . . What the company is trying to
  do is prevent the passengers who can pay the second-class fare
  from travelling third class; it hits the poor, not because it wants to
  hurt them, but to frighten the rich. . . (Ekelund [1970])
Note that the distortion of qL away from its optimal level is a
market failure.
Note that the distortion of qL away from its optimal level is a
market failure.
However, it does not follow that the optimal policy is to
prevent firms from second degree discrimination. . .
Second-degree discrimination & social welfare
       What will the firm do if it cannot price discriminate?
Second-degree discrimination & social welfare
       What will the firm do if it cannot price discriminate?
                            ∗              ∗       ∗              ∗
       Will provide either qH at price θH qH , or qL at price θL qL .
Second-degree discrimination & social welfare
       What will the firm do if it cannot price discriminate?
                            ∗              ∗        ∗             ∗
       Will provide either qH at price θH qH , or qL at price θL qL .
       In the efficient allocation, social welfare is
                      ∗      ∗                   ∗      ∗
               α [θL qL − C(qL )] + (1 − α) [θH qH − C(qH )] .
       (we can ignore the ps which simply move surplus around).
Second-degree discrimination & social welfare
       What will the firm do if it cannot price discriminate?
                            ∗              ∗        ∗             ∗
       Will provide either qH at price θH qH , or qL at price θL qL .
       In the efficient allocation, social welfare is
                      ∗      ∗                   ∗      ∗
               α [θL qL − C(qL )] + (1 − α) [θH qH − C(qH )] .
       (we can ignore the ps which simply move surplus around).
       In the second order price discrimination case, social welfare is
                                                 ∗      ∗
               α [θL qL − C(qL )] + (1 − α) [θH qH − C(qH )] .
Second-degree discrimination & social welfare
       What will the firm do if it cannot price discriminate?
                            ∗              ∗        ∗             ∗
       Will provide either qH at price θH qH , or qL at price θL qL .
       In the efficient allocation, social welfare is
                      ∗      ∗                   ∗      ∗
               α [θL qL − C(qL )] + (1 − α) [θH qH − C(qH )] .
       (we can ignore the ps which simply move surplus around).
       In the second order price discrimination case, social welfare is
                                                 ∗      ∗
               α [θL qL − C(qL )] + (1 − α) [θH qH − C(qH )] .

                              ∗
       If the firm offers only qH , social welfare is
                                       ∗      ∗
                          (1 − α) [θH qH − C(qH )] .
       Thus social welfare falls.
Second-degree discrimination & social welfare
       What will the firm do if it cannot price discriminate?
                            ∗              ∗        ∗             ∗
       Will provide either qH at price θH qH , or qL at price θL qL .
       In the efficient allocation, social welfare is
                      ∗      ∗                   ∗      ∗
               α [θL qL − C(qL )] + (1 − α) [θH qH − C(qH )] .
       (we can ignore the ps which simply move surplus around).
       In the second order price discrimination case, social welfare is
                                                 ∗      ∗
               α [θL qL − C(qL )] + (1 − α) [θH qH − C(qH )] .

                              ∗
       If the firm offers only qH , social welfare is
                                       ∗      ∗
                          (1 − α) [θH qH − C(qH )] .
       Thus social welfare falls.
                               ∗
       If the firm offers only qL , social welfare is
                       ∗      ∗                   ∗      ∗
                α [θL qL − C(qL )] + (1 − α) [θH qL − C(qL )] ,
       so that welfare may fall or increase relative to second-order
       PD.
More current examples




      In fact, when one thinks about it, there are similar-looking
      cases in many information markets:
More current examples
More current examples
More current examples
More current examples
More current examples
Outline




   Price discrimination: from assumptions to policy statements



   Assumptions and applicability
Assumptions, assumptions. . .



       But these examples are a little different to the ones considered
       before:
           Cost to MS of “surprising” a customer by giving them the
           professional, rather than home edition of Windows is basically
           zero.
Assumptions, assumptions. . .



       But these examples are a little different to the ones considered
       before:
           Cost to MS of “surprising” a customer by giving them the
           professional, rather than home edition of Windows is basically
           zero.
           Corresponds to C (q) = 0, C (q) = 0—which is contrary to
           our assumptions.
Assumptions, assumptions. . .



       But these examples are a little different to the ones considered
       before:
           Cost to MS of “surprising” a customer by giving them the
           professional, rather than home edition of Windows is basically
           zero.
           Corresponds to C (q) = 0, C (q) = 0—which is contrary to
           our assumptions.
       When we try to put this into the model things break down.
       Let’s see why. . .
Graphical treatment (assuming α = 1/2)
          Price




                                         Quantity
                                         Quality
Graphical treatment (assuming α = 1/2)
          Price




         θH




                                         Quantity
                                         Quality
Graphical treatment (assuming α = 1/2)
          Price

                                Willingness to pay


         θH




                                                     Quantity
                           qH                        Quality
Graphical treatment (assuming α = 1/2)
          Price
                                          C’(q)




                                         Quantity
                                         Quality
Graphical treatment (assuming α = 1/2)
          Price
                                                 C’(q)
                           Cost of production




                                                Quantity
                                  qH
                                                Quality
Graphical treatment (assuming α = 1/2)
          Price
                                          C’(q)



         θH




         θL




                                         Quantity
                                         Quality
First degree discrimination
           Price
                                         C’(q)



          θH




          θL




                                        Quantity
                              qL
                               *   qH
                                    *
                                        Quality
Graphical treatment
               Price
                       CS of high types from buying         C’(q)
                             low quality good


           θH



               pL
        θ L=
               qL




                                                           Quantity
                                               qL     qH   Quality
Graphical treatment
               Price
                            CS of high types from buying         C’(q)
                                  low quality good


              θH



              pL
       θ L=
              qL




                                                                Quantity
                       qL                                  qH   Quality
Graphical treatment
               Price
                                  C’(q)



           θH
           pH
           qH

               pL
        θ L=
               qL




                                 Quantity
                       qL   qH   Quality
Graphical treatment
               Price
                            CS of high types from buying         C’(q)
                                  high quality good


              θH
              pH
              qH

              pL
       θ L=
              qL




                                                                Quantity
                       qL                                  qH   Quality
Graphical treatment
               Price
                                         C’(q)



           θH



               pL
        θ L=
               qL




                                        Quantity
                       qL   qL+Δ   qH   Quality
Graphical treatment
               Price
                            Loss (must reduce pH to maintain ICH)    C’(q)



              θH



              pL
       θ L=
              qL




                                                                    Quantity
                       qL   qL+Δ                               qH   Quality
Graphical treatment
               Price
                            Loss (must reduce pH to maintain ICH)     C’(q)



           θH



               pL
        θ L=
               qL


                                        Gain (can charge more
                                       to low type consumers)

                                      Loss (higher q is more
                                      expensive to produce)


                                                                     Quantity
                       qL   qL+Δ                                qH   Quality
Graphical treatment
               Price
                                       C’(q)



              θH



              pL
       θ L=
              qL




                                      Quantity
                       qL   qL
                             *   qH
                                  *
                                      Quality
Constant marginal cost
                Price




               θH



               pL
        θ L=
               qL




                         C’(q)




                         Quantity
                         Quality
What goes wrong?
               Price




              θH



              pL
       θ L=
              qL




                               C’(q)




                               Quantity
                   qL   qL+Δ   Quality
What goes wrong? (i)
               Price




              θH



              pL
       θ L=
              qL




                                           C’(q)




                                           Quantity
                   qL   qL+Δ   qL   qL+Δ   Quality
What goes wrong? (ii)
               Price




              θH




              pL
       θ L=
              qL


                                           C’(q)




                                           Quantity
                   qL   qL+Δ   qL   qL+Δ   Quality
Declining marginal willingness to pay.
           Price




               θH




                                         C’(q)


                            θL

                                         Quantity
                                         Quality
Declining marginal willingness to pay.
           Price
                             Declining ΔWTP



               θH




                                              Quantity
                    Δq                 Δq     Quality
First degree descrimination.
           Price




               θH




                                         C’(q)


                               θL

                                         Quantity
                     qL             qH   Quality
Profit effect of a quality increase.
           Price              Loss (Need to lower pH to maintain ICH)




               θH

                                 Gain (Can charge more to low value consumers)




                                                                    C’(q)


                                   θL

                                                                        Quantity
                    qL   qL
                          *                   qH
                                               *
                                                                        Quality
Other assumptions




   In a similar manner, one can relax other assumptions e.g.:
       Oligopoly suppliers.
       Many consumer types.
       Non-continuous q.
Summary

     Social science is about understanding society.
Summary

     Social science is about understanding society.
     That, at least in part, means trying to understand the
     fundamental forces that drive social phenomena.
Summary

     Social science is about understanding society.
     That, at least in part, means trying to understand the
     fundamental forces that drive social phenomena.
     Often, behaviour is fundamentally unchanged by new
     technology. Looking into the past can offer hints on how to
     understand and interpret the present.
Summary

     Social science is about understanding society.
     That, at least in part, means trying to understand the
     fundamental forces that drive social phenomena.
     Often, behaviour is fundamentally unchanged by new
     technology. Looking into the past can offer hints on how to
     understand and interpret the present.
     Moreover, the result of linking related phenomena is often an
     insight that exceeds the sum of its parts.
Summary

     Social science is about understanding society.
     That, at least in part, means trying to understand the
     fundamental forces that drive social phenomena.
     Often, behaviour is fundamentally unchanged by new
     technology. Looking into the past can offer hints on how to
     understand and interpret the present.
     Moreover, the result of linking related phenomena is often an
     insight that exceeds the sum of its parts.
     Sometimes the process works backwards: new contexts can
     generate insights into old puzzles—e.g. two-sided markets.
Summary

     Social science is about understanding society.
     That, at least in part, means trying to understand the
     fundamental forces that drive social phenomena.
     Often, behaviour is fundamentally unchanged by new
     technology. Looking into the past can offer hints on how to
     understand and interpret the present.
     Moreover, the result of linking related phenomena is often an
     insight that exceeds the sum of its parts.
     Sometimes the process works backwards: new contexts can
     generate insights into old puzzles—e.g. two-sided markets.
     A key ingredient in making these links is an understanding of
     the assumptions upon which alternative conceptualisations are
     predicated.
Summary

     Social science is about understanding society.
     That, at least in part, means trying to understand the
     fundamental forces that drive social phenomena.
     Often, behaviour is fundamentally unchanged by new
     technology. Looking into the past can offer hints on how to
     understand and interpret the present.
     Moreover, the result of linking related phenomena is often an
     insight that exceeds the sum of its parts.
     Sometimes the process works backwards: new contexts can
     generate insights into old puzzles—e.g. two-sided markets.
     A key ingredient in making these links is an understanding of
     the assumptions upon which alternative conceptualisations are
     predicated.

Mais conteúdo relacionado

Destaque

The Structure of Political Discussion Networks
The Structure of Political Discussion Networks The Structure of Political Discussion Networks
The Structure of Political Discussion Networks oiisdp2010
 
Firefox instructions for PC
Firefox instructions for PCFirefox instructions for PC
Firefox instructions for PCoiisdp2010
 
Mac safari setup
Mac safari setupMac safari setup
Mac safari setupoiisdp2010
 
Digital gaming, racial and ethnic identity, and social justice
Digital gaming, racial and ethnic identity, and social justice Digital gaming, racial and ethnic identity, and social justice
Digital gaming, racial and ethnic identity, and social justice oiisdp2010
 
Firefox instructions for Macintosh
Firefox instructions for MacintoshFirefox instructions for Macintosh
Firefox instructions for Macintoshoiisdp2010
 
Safari instructions
Safari instructionsSafari instructions
Safari instructionsoiisdp2010
 
Internet Explorer instructions
Internet Explorer instructionsInternet Explorer instructions
Internet Explorer instructionsoiisdp2010
 
e-Harmony Study
e-Harmony Study e-Harmony Study
e-Harmony Study oiisdp2010
 

Destaque (9)

Quieres participar
Quieres  participarQuieres  participar
Quieres participar
 
The Structure of Political Discussion Networks
The Structure of Political Discussion Networks The Structure of Political Discussion Networks
The Structure of Political Discussion Networks
 
Firefox instructions for PC
Firefox instructions for PCFirefox instructions for PC
Firefox instructions for PC
 
Mac safari setup
Mac safari setupMac safari setup
Mac safari setup
 
Digital gaming, racial and ethnic identity, and social justice
Digital gaming, racial and ethnic identity, and social justice Digital gaming, racial and ethnic identity, and social justice
Digital gaming, racial and ethnic identity, and social justice
 
Firefox instructions for Macintosh
Firefox instructions for MacintoshFirefox instructions for Macintosh
Firefox instructions for Macintosh
 
Safari instructions
Safari instructionsSafari instructions
Safari instructions
 
Internet Explorer instructions
Internet Explorer instructionsInternet Explorer instructions
Internet Explorer instructions
 
e-Harmony Study
e-Harmony Study e-Harmony Study
e-Harmony Study
 

Semelhante a Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Principles of Microeconomics Notes
Principles of Microeconomics NotesPrinciples of Microeconomics Notes
Principles of Microeconomics NotesLaurel Ayuyao
 
Bertrand competition presentation
Bertrand competition presentationBertrand competition presentation
Bertrand competition presentationRobin McKinnie
 
Problem Set 2.pdfProblem Set 2 ECO105 Industrial Organiz.docx
Problem Set 2.pdfProblem Set 2 ECO105 Industrial Organiz.docxProblem Set 2.pdfProblem Set 2 ECO105 Industrial Organiz.docx
Problem Set 2.pdfProblem Set 2 ECO105 Industrial Organiz.docxwkyra78
 
1 s2.0-0022199679900175-main
1 s2.0-0022199679900175-main1 s2.0-0022199679900175-main
1 s2.0-0022199679900175-mainjhetrocio
 
Monopolylecture 2
Monopolylecture 2Monopolylecture 2
Monopolylecture 2Rahul Singh
 
Ch. 3-demand-theory
Ch. 3-demand-theoryCh. 3-demand-theory
Ch. 3-demand-theoryanj134u
 
Monopoly SFLS online
Monopoly SFLS onlineMonopoly SFLS online
Monopoly SFLS onlineianhorner3
 
Monopoly and Perfect Competition
Monopoly and Perfect CompetitionMonopoly and Perfect Competition
Monopoly and Perfect CompetitionSamiran Halder
 
Price Discrimination.ppt
Price Discrimination.pptPrice Discrimination.ppt
Price Discrimination.pptKNTLZeus
 
Ap microeconomics revew slides
Ap microeconomics revew slidesAp microeconomics revew slides
Ap microeconomics revew slidesStephen Staunton
 
Slides 15(Chapter 22)What do we mean by network ef.docx
Slides 15(Chapter 22)What do we mean by network ef.docxSlides 15(Chapter 22)What do we mean by network ef.docx
Slides 15(Chapter 22)What do we mean by network ef.docxwhitneyleman54422
 
Chapter 3 theory of consumer behavior
Chapter 3  theory of consumer behaviorChapter 3  theory of consumer behavior
Chapter 3 theory of consumer behaviorNajeebhemat Malikzia
 
2 demand-supply and elasticity
2  demand-supply and elasticity2  demand-supply and elasticity
2 demand-supply and elasticitydannygriff1
 
Chapter_1_theory_of_consumer_behavior.ppt
Chapter_1_theory_of_consumer_behavior.pptChapter_1_theory_of_consumer_behavior.ppt
Chapter_1_theory_of_consumer_behavior.pptJamesMumba8
 
Monopoly and monopolistic competition
Monopoly and monopolistic competitionMonopoly and monopolistic competition
Monopoly and monopolistic competitionCustomResearchPapers1
 

Semelhante a Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet (20)

Principles of Microeconomics Notes
Principles of Microeconomics NotesPrinciples of Microeconomics Notes
Principles of Microeconomics Notes
 
Bertrand competition presentation
Bertrand competition presentationBertrand competition presentation
Bertrand competition presentation
 
Problem Set 2.pdfProblem Set 2 ECO105 Industrial Organiz.docx
Problem Set 2.pdfProblem Set 2 ECO105 Industrial Organiz.docxProblem Set 2.pdfProblem Set 2 ECO105 Industrial Organiz.docx
Problem Set 2.pdfProblem Set 2 ECO105 Industrial Organiz.docx
 
J1
J1J1
J1
 
1 s2.0-0022199679900175-main
1 s2.0-0022199679900175-main1 s2.0-0022199679900175-main
1 s2.0-0022199679900175-main
 
Monopolylecture 2
Monopolylecture 2Monopolylecture 2
Monopolylecture 2
 
Material 2 funcion lineal
Material 2   funcion linealMaterial 2   funcion lineal
Material 2 funcion lineal
 
Ch. 3-demand-theory
Ch. 3-demand-theoryCh. 3-demand-theory
Ch. 3-demand-theory
 
Monopoly SFLS online
Monopoly SFLS onlineMonopoly SFLS online
Monopoly SFLS online
 
Monopoly and Perfect Competition
Monopoly and Perfect CompetitionMonopoly and Perfect Competition
Monopoly and Perfect Competition
 
Financial modeling for startups
Financial modeling for startupsFinancial modeling for startups
Financial modeling for startups
 
Price Discrimination.ppt
Price Discrimination.pptPrice Discrimination.ppt
Price Discrimination.ppt
 
Ap microeconomics revew slides
Ap microeconomics revew slidesAp microeconomics revew slides
Ap microeconomics revew slides
 
Slides 15(Chapter 22)What do we mean by network ef.docx
Slides 15(Chapter 22)What do we mean by network ef.docxSlides 15(Chapter 22)What do we mean by network ef.docx
Slides 15(Chapter 22)What do we mean by network ef.docx
 
Chapter 3 theory of consumer behavior
Chapter 3  theory of consumer behaviorChapter 3  theory of consumer behavior
Chapter 3 theory of consumer behavior
 
2 demand-supply and elasticity
2  demand-supply and elasticity2  demand-supply and elasticity
2 demand-supply and elasticity
 
041013
041013041013
041013
 
Chapter_1_theory_of_consumer_behavior.ppt
Chapter_1_theory_of_consumer_behavior.pptChapter_1_theory_of_consumer_behavior.ppt
Chapter_1_theory_of_consumer_behavior.ppt
 
Monopoly and monopolistic competition
Monopoly and monopolistic competitionMonopoly and monopolistic competition
Monopoly and monopolistic competition
 
Financial modeling for startups
Financial modeling for startupsFinancial modeling for startups
Financial modeling for startups
 

Último

BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK  LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdfBASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK  LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdfSoniaTolstoy
 
Beyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global Impact
Beyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global ImpactBeyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global Impact
Beyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global ImpactPECB
 
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...Krashi Coaching
 
Unit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptx
Unit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptxUnit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptx
Unit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptxVishalSingh1417
 
APM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across Sectors
APM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across SectorsAPM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across Sectors
APM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across SectorsAssociation for Project Management
 
Disha NEET Physics Guide for classes 11 and 12.pdf
Disha NEET Physics Guide for classes 11 and 12.pdfDisha NEET Physics Guide for classes 11 and 12.pdf
Disha NEET Physics Guide for classes 11 and 12.pdfchloefrazer622
 
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptxSOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptxiammrhaywood
 
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13Steve Thomason
 
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introductionmicrowave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introductionMaksud Ahmed
 
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy Reform
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy ReformA Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy Reform
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy ReformChameera Dedduwage
 
Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3
Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3
Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3JemimahLaneBuaron
 
1029 - Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf
1029 -  Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf1029 -  Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf
1029 - Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdfQucHHunhnh
 
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communication
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communicationInteractive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communication
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communicationnomboosow
 
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and Mode
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and ModeMeasures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and Mode
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and ModeThiyagu K
 
Measures of Dispersion and Variability: Range, QD, AD and SD
Measures of Dispersion and Variability: Range, QD, AD and SDMeasures of Dispersion and Variability: Range, QD, AD and SD
Measures of Dispersion and Variability: Range, QD, AD and SDThiyagu K
 
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot GraphZ Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot GraphThiyagu K
 
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi 6.pdf
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi  6.pdf1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi  6.pdf
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi 6.pdfQucHHunhnh
 
social pharmacy d-pharm 1st year by Pragati K. Mahajan
social pharmacy d-pharm 1st year by Pragati K. Mahajansocial pharmacy d-pharm 1st year by Pragati K. Mahajan
social pharmacy d-pharm 1st year by Pragati K. Mahajanpragatimahajan3
 
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impactAccessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impactdawncurless
 

Último (20)

BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK  LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdfBASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK  LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
 
Beyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global Impact
Beyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global ImpactBeyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global Impact
Beyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global Impact
 
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
 
Unit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptx
Unit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptxUnit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptx
Unit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptx
 
APM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across Sectors
APM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across SectorsAPM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across Sectors
APM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across Sectors
 
Disha NEET Physics Guide for classes 11 and 12.pdf
Disha NEET Physics Guide for classes 11 and 12.pdfDisha NEET Physics Guide for classes 11 and 12.pdf
Disha NEET Physics Guide for classes 11 and 12.pdf
 
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptxSOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
 
Advance Mobile Application Development class 07
Advance Mobile Application Development class 07Advance Mobile Application Development class 07
Advance Mobile Application Development class 07
 
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13
 
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introductionmicrowave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
 
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy Reform
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy ReformA Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy Reform
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy Reform
 
Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3
Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3
Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3
 
1029 - Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf
1029 -  Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf1029 -  Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf
1029 - Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf
 
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communication
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communicationInteractive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communication
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communication
 
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and Mode
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and ModeMeasures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and Mode
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and Mode
 
Measures of Dispersion and Variability: Range, QD, AD and SD
Measures of Dispersion and Variability: Range, QD, AD and SDMeasures of Dispersion and Variability: Range, QD, AD and SD
Measures of Dispersion and Variability: Range, QD, AD and SD
 
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot GraphZ Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
 
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi 6.pdf
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi  6.pdf1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi  6.pdf
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi 6.pdf
 
social pharmacy d-pharm 1st year by Pragati K. Mahajan
social pharmacy d-pharm 1st year by Pragati K. Mahajansocial pharmacy d-pharm 1st year by Pragati K. Mahajan
social pharmacy d-pharm 1st year by Pragati K. Mahajan
 
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impactAccessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
 

Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

  • 1. Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet Some Lessons From the Past Greg Taylor Oxford Internet Institute University of Oxford
  • 2. Economics The study of constrained choice.
  • 3. Economics The study of constrained choice. Build mathematical models of decision makers’ behaviours.
  • 4. Economics The study of constrained choice. Build mathematical models of decision makers’ behaviours. Typically gives us very sharp conclusions.
  • 5. Economics The study of constrained choice. Build mathematical models of decision makers’ behaviours. Typically gives us very sharp conclusions. Suggests effects of policy changes—comparative statics.
  • 6. Economics The study of constrained choice. Build mathematical models of decision makers’ behaviours. Typically gives us very sharp conclusions. Suggests effects of policy changes—comparative statics. But hard: the world is very complex, so we need assumptions.
  • 7. Economics The study of constrained choice. Build mathematical models of decision makers’ behaviours. Typically gives us very sharp conclusions. Suggests effects of policy changes—comparative statics. But hard: the world is very complex, so we need assumptions. Thus another advantage of the mathematical approach: encourages transparency of assumptions.
  • 8. Economics The study of constrained choice. Build mathematical models of decision makers’ behaviours. Typically gives us very sharp conclusions. Suggests effects of policy changes—comparative statics. But hard: the world is very complex, so we need assumptions. Thus another advantage of the mathematical approach: encourages transparency of assumptions. Let’s take a look at a textbook example of how some simple assumptions can be turned into a model.
  • 9. Outline Price discrimination: from assumptions to policy statements Assumptions and applicability
  • 10. Price discrimination Price discrimination is the practice of pricing such that different groups of consumers yield different price-cost margins for the firm.
  • 11. A price discrimination example Imagine a monopolist firm that sells some products of varying quality.
  • 12. A price discrimination example Imagine a monopolist firm that sells some products of varying quality. Assume that quality can be indexed by a number, q. Let q be continuous. Suppose that it costs C(q) to provide a product with quality q. Let C (q) > 0 (increasing costs), C (q) > 0 (convex costs), and C(0) = 0.
  • 13. A price discrimination example Imagine a monopolist firm that sells some products of varying quality. Assume that quality can be indexed by a number, q. Let q be continuous. Suppose that it costs C(q) to provide a product with quality q. Let C (q) > 0 (increasing costs), C (q) > 0 (convex costs), and C(0) = 0. There are two types of customer: low (L), and high (H).
  • 14. A price discrimination example Imagine a monopolist firm that sells some products of varying quality. Assume that quality can be indexed by a number, q. Let q be continuous. Suppose that it costs C(q) to provide a product with quality q. Let C (q) > 0 (increasing costs), C (q) > 0 (convex costs), and C(0) = 0. There are two types of customer: low (L), and high (H). A type i ∈ {L, H} consumer enjoys surplus Ui = θi q − p. where p is the price to be paid to the firm, and θi is the consumer’s willingness to pay for a one unit increase in quality.
  • 15. A price discrimination example Imagine a monopolist firm that sells some products of varying quality. Assume that quality can be indexed by a number, q. Let q be continuous. Suppose that it costs C(q) to provide a product with quality q. Let C (q) > 0 (increasing costs), C (q) > 0 (convex costs), and C(0) = 0. There are two types of customer: low (L), and high (H). A type i ∈ {L, H} consumer enjoys surplus Ui = θi q − p. where p is the price to be paid to the firm, and θi is the consumer’s willingness to pay for a one unit increase in quality. Let θL < θH .
  • 16. First order discrimination In a perfect world, the firm would know the type of consumer it is facing. It could then design a product/price combination for each type.
  • 17. First order discrimination In a perfect world, the firm would know the type of consumer it is facing. It could then design a product/price combination for each type. i.e. Sell a ‘budget’ product with q = qL at price pL to L-type consumers, and a ‘luxury’ product with q = qH at price pH .
  • 18. First order discrimination In a perfect world, the firm would know the type of consumer it is facing. It could then design a product/price combination for each type. i.e. Sell a ‘budget’ product with q = qL at price pL to L-type consumers, and a ‘luxury’ product with q = qH at price pH . The firm’s objective would then be to max pi − C(qi ) qi ,pi
  • 19. First order discrimination In a perfect world, the firm would know the type of consumer it is facing. It could then design a product/price combination for each type. i.e. Sell a ‘budget’ product with q = qL at price pL to L-type consumers, and a ‘luxury’ product with q = qH at price pH . The firm’s objective would then be to max pi − C(qi ) qi ,pi subject to the constraint θi qi − pi ≥ 0.
  • 20. First order discrimination In a perfect world, the firm would know the type of consumer it is facing. It could then design a product/price combination for each type. i.e. Sell a ‘budget’ product with q = qL at price pL to L-type consumers, and a ‘luxury’ product with q = qH at price pH . The firm’s objective would then be to max pi − C(qi ) qi ,pi subject to the constraint θi qi − pi ≥ 0. This kind of behaviour is called first degree price discrimination.
  • 21. First order discrimination max pi − C(qi ) s.t. θi qi − pi ≥ 0. qi ,pi
  • 22. First order discrimination max pi − C(qi ) s.t. θi qi − pi ≥ 0. qi ,pi In fact, since the firm knows θi , it can just set pi = θi qi .
  • 23. First order discrimination max pi − C(qi ) s.t. θi qi − pi ≥ 0. qi ,pi In fact, since the firm knows θi , it can just set pi = θi qi . Substituting this into the maximisation problem gives max θi qi − C(qi ). qi
  • 24. First order discrimination max pi − C(qi ) s.t. θi qi − pi ≥ 0. qi ,pi In fact, since the firm knows θi , it can just set pi = θi qi . Substituting this into the maximisation problem gives max θi qi − C(qi ). qi Increasing qi by one unit increases revenue by θi , and cost by C (qi ).
  • 25. First order discrimination max pi − C(qi ) s.t. θi qi − pi ≥ 0. qi ,pi In fact, since the firm knows θi , it can just set pi = θi qi . Substituting this into the maximisation problem gives max θi qi − C(qi ). qi Increasing qi by one unit increases revenue by θi , and cost by C (qi ). It is therefore profitable to increase quality if and only if θi > C (qi ).
  • 26. First order discrimination max pi − C(qi ) s.t. θi qi − pi ≥ 0. qi ,pi In fact, since the firm knows θi , it can just set pi = θi qi . Substituting this into the maximisation problem gives max θi qi − C(qi ). qi Increasing qi by one unit increases revenue by θi , and cost by C (qi ). It is therefore profitable to increase quality if and only if θi > C (qi ). ∗ So quality qi is produced where θi = C (qi ), i.e. where marginal cost of qi is equal to marginal willingness to pay for it.
  • 27. What can we say about these qs? Firstly, by giving firms so much information about consumers, we have left the latter with no surplus.
  • 28. What can we say about these qs? Firstly, by giving firms so much information about consumers, we have left the latter with no surplus. However, that θi = C (qi ) implies the chosen qualities are efficient!
  • 29. What can we say about these qs? Firstly, by giving firms so much information about consumers, we have left the latter with no surplus. However, that θi = C (qi ) implies the chosen qualities are efficient! Social welfare given by consumer + firm welfare: (θi qi − p) + (p − C(qi ))
  • 30. What can we say about these qs? Firstly, by giving firms so much information about consumers, we have left the latter with no surplus. However, that θi = C (qi ) implies the chosen qualities are efficient! Social welfare given by consumer + firm welfare: (θi qi − p) + (p − C(qi )) = θi qi − C(qi ). This is exactly what the firm is maximising!
  • 31. What can we say about these qs? Firstly, by giving firms so much information about consumers, we have left the latter with no surplus. However, that θi = C (qi ) implies the chosen qualities are efficient! Social welfare given by consumer + firm welfare: (θi qi − p) + (p − C(qi )) = θi qi − C(qi ). This is exactly what the firm is maximising! That θi = C (qi ) also implies that qL < qH , and hence pL < pH .
  • 32. What can we say about these qs? Firstly, by giving firms so much information about consumers, we have left the latter with no surplus. However, that θi = C (qi ) implies the chosen qualities are efficient! Social welfare given by consumer + firm welfare: (θi qi − p) + (p − C(qi )) = θi qi − C(qi ). This is exactly what the firm is maximising! That θi = C (qi ) also implies that qL < qH , and hence pL < pH .
  • 33. Segmentation breakdown Now, firms typically cannot observe θi and so must depend on the consumer to buy the product designed for them.
  • 34. Segmentation breakdown Now, firms typically cannot observe θi and so must depend on the consumer to buy the product designed for them. Therein lies a problem: if high consumers buy the high quality product, they get θH qH − pH = θH qH − θH qH = 0,
  • 35. Segmentation breakdown Now, firms typically cannot observe θi and so must depend on the consumer to buy the product designed for them. Therein lies a problem: if high consumers buy the high quality product, they get θH qH − pH = θH qH − θH qH = 0, whereas if they buy the low quality product, they get θ H qL − p L
  • 36. Segmentation breakdown Now, firms typically cannot observe θi and so must depend on the consumer to buy the product designed for them. Therein lies a problem: if high consumers buy the high quality product, they get θH qH − pH = θH qH − θH qH = 0, whereas if they buy the low quality product, they get θH qL − pL > θL qL − pL
  • 37. Segmentation breakdown Now, firms typically cannot observe θi and so must depend on the consumer to buy the product designed for them. Therein lies a problem: if high consumers buy the high quality product, they get θH qH − pH = θH qH − θH qH = 0, whereas if they buy the low quality product, they get θH qL − pL > θL qL − pL = 0.
  • 38. Segmentation breakdown Now, firms typically cannot observe θi and so must depend on the consumer to buy the product designed for them. Therein lies a problem: if high consumers buy the high quality product, they get θH qH − pH = θH qH − θH qH = 0, whereas if they buy the low quality product, they get θH qL − pL > θL qL − pL = 0. Thus, all consumers will buy the budget product—this is called adverse selection.
  • 39. Solution: mechanism design Question: What can the firm do about this?
  • 40. Solution: mechanism design Question: What can the firm do about this? Answer: Change it’s maximisation problem.
  • 41. Solution: mechanism design Question: What can the firm do about this? Answer: Change it’s maximisation problem. Suppose a consumer is of type L with probability α and of type H with probability (1 − α).
  • 42. Solution: mechanism design Question: What can the firm do about this? Answer: Change it’s maximisation problem. Suppose a consumer is of type L with probability α and of type H with probability (1 − α). The new problem is then: max α(pL − C(qL )) + (1 − α)(pH − C(qH )) qL ,pL ,qH ,pH
  • 43. Solution: mechanism design Question: What can the firm do about this? Answer: Change it’s maximisation problem. Suppose a consumer is of type L with probability α and of type H with probability (1 − α). The new problem is then: max α(pL − C(qL )) + (1 − α)(pH − C(qH )) qL ,pL ,qH ,pH subject to the constraint θH qH − pH ≥ θH qL − pL (ICH) θ L qL − p L ≥ θ H qH − p H (ICL) θH qH − pH ≥ 0 (IRH) θL qL − pL ≥ 0 (IRL)
  • 44. Solution: mechanism design Question: What can the firm do about this? Answer: Change it’s maximisation problem. Suppose a consumer is of type L with probability α and of type H with probability (1 − α). The new problem is then: max α(pL − C(qL )) + (1 − α)(pH − C(qH )) qL ,pL ,qH ,pH subject to the constraint θH qH − pH ≥ θH qL − pL (ICH) θ L qL − p L ≥ θ H qH − p H (ICL) θH qH − pH ≥ 0 (IRH) θL qL − pL ≥ 0 (IRL) Solving such a problem is known as second degree price discrimination.
  • 45. IRL is ‘binding’ Let’s begin by establishing that IRL holds with equality i.e. that θL qL − pL = 0. This means that home users are left with no surplus.
  • 46. IRL is ‘binding’ Let’s begin by establishing that IRL holds with equality i.e. that θL qL − pL = 0. This means that home users are left with no surplus. ICH says θ H qH − p H ≥ θ H qL − p L
  • 47. IRL is ‘binding’ Let’s begin by establishing that IRL holds with equality i.e. that θL qL − pL = 0. This means that home users are left with no surplus. ICH says θ H qH − p H ≥ θ H qL − p L ≥ θ L qL − p L
  • 48. IRL is ‘binding’ Let’s begin by establishing that IRL holds with equality i.e. that θL qL − pL = 0. This means that home users are left with no surplus. ICH says θ H qH − p H ≥ θ H qL − p L ≥ θ L qL − p L Thus, if θL qL − pL > 0, then it must also be true that θH qH − pH > 0 so that neither IRL nor IRH bind.
  • 49. IRL is ‘binding’ Let’s begin by establishing that IRL holds with equality i.e. that θL qL − pL = 0. This means that home users are left with no surplus. ICH says θ H qH − p H ≥ θ H qL − p L ≥ θ L qL − p L Thus, if θL qL − pL > 0, then it must also be true that θH qH − pH > 0 so that neither IRL nor IRH bind. But then the firm could increase both pL and pH without violating any condition.
  • 50. IRL is ‘binding’ Let’s begin by establishing that IRL holds with equality i.e. that θL qL − pL = 0. This means that home users are left with no surplus. ICH says θ H qH − p H ≥ θ H qL − p L ≥ θ L qL − p L Thus, if θL qL − pL > 0, then it must also be true that θH qH − pH > 0 so that neither IRL nor IRH bind. But then the firm could increase both pL and pH without violating any condition. This implies that IRL must bind at the optimum.
  • 51. ICH is ‘binding’ We next show that ICH holds with equality i.e. that θ H qH − p H = θ H qL − p L . This means if the deal for the luxury product got any worse then H type consumers would switch to buying the budget product.
  • 52. ICH is ‘binding’ We next show that ICH holds with equality i.e. that θ H qH − p H = θ H qL − p L . This means if the deal for the luxury product got any worse then H type consumers would switch to buying the budget product. Suppose that this weren’t true: θH qH − pH > θH qL − pL
  • 53. ICH is ‘binding’ We next show that ICH holds with equality i.e. that θ H qH − p H = θ H qL − p L . This means if the deal for the luxury product got any worse then H type consumers would switch to buying the budget product. Suppose that this weren’t true: θH qH − pH > θH qL − pL ≥ θL qL − pL
  • 54. ICH is ‘binding’ We next show that ICH holds with equality i.e. that θ H qH − p H = θ H qL − p L . This means if the deal for the luxury product got any worse then H type consumers would switch to buying the budget product. Suppose that this weren’t true: θH qH − pH > θH qL − pL ≥ θL qL − pL = 0
  • 55. ICH is ‘binding’ We next show that ICH holds with equality i.e. that θ H qH − p H = θ H qL − p L . This means if the deal for the luxury product got any worse then H type consumers would switch to buying the budget product. Suppose that this weren’t true: θH qH − pH > θH qL − pL ≥ θL qL − pL = 0 Thus, if ICH does not bind then neither does IRH.
  • 56. ICH is ‘binding’ We next show that ICH holds with equality i.e. that θ H qH − p H = θ H qL − p L . This means if the deal for the luxury product got any worse then H type consumers would switch to buying the budget product. Suppose that this weren’t true: θH qH − pH > θH qL − pL ≥ θL qL − pL = 0 Thus, if ICH does not bind then neither does IRH. But then the firm could increase pH without violating any condition.
  • 57. ICH is ‘binding’ We next show that ICH holds with equality i.e. that θ H qH − p H = θ H qL − p L . This means if the deal for the luxury product got any worse then H type consumers would switch to buying the budget product. Suppose that this weren’t true: θH qH − pH > θH qL − pL ≥ θL qL − pL = 0 Thus, if ICH does not bind then neither does IRH. But then the firm could increase pH without violating any condition. This implies that ICH must bind at the optimum.
  • 58. Can neglect IRH and ICL That ICH binds implies θH qH − pH = θH qL − pL .
  • 59. Can neglect IRH and ICL That ICH binds implies θH qH − pH = θH qL − pL . IRL implies θL qL − pL = 0.
  • 60. Can neglect IRH and ICL That ICH binds implies θH qH − pH = θH qL − pL . IRL implies θL qL − pL = 0. Thus we have θH qH − pH = θH qL − pH > θL qL − pL = 0.
  • 61. Can neglect IRH and ICL That ICH binds implies θH qH − pH = θH qL − pL . IRL implies θL qL − pL = 0. Thus we have θH qH − pH = θH qL − pH > θL qL − pL = 0. So IRH can be neglected.
  • 62. Can neglect IRH and ICL That ICH binds implies θH qH − pH = θH qL − pL . IRL implies θL qL − pL = 0. Thus we have θH qH − pH = θH qL − pH > θL qL − pL = 0. So IRH can be neglected. This means that business customers get strictly positive utility.
  • 63. Can neglect ICL It can also be shown that ICL does not bind. Briefly: since ICH binds θH (qH − qL ) = pH − pL .
  • 64. Can neglect ICL It can also be shown that ICL does not bind. Briefly: since ICH binds θH (qH − qL ) = pH − pL . But ICL says (after rearranging) θL (qH − qL ) ≤ pH − pL .
  • 65. Can neglect ICL It can also be shown that ICL does not bind. Briefly: since ICH binds θH (qH − qL ) = pH − pL . But ICL says (after rearranging) θL (qH − qL ) ≤ pH − pL . The inequality must be strict since θH > θL .
  • 66. Can neglect ICL It can also be shown that ICL does not bind. Briefly: since ICH binds θH (qH − qL ) = pH − pL . But ICL says (after rearranging) θL (qH − qL ) ≤ pH − pL . The inequality must be strict since θH > θL . This means that the home bundle is strictly more attractive to home users than is the business edition.
  • 67. qH is the set at the efficient level ∗ Now we will show that the chosen qH is qH —i.e. where C (qH ) = θH just like in the first order discrimination case. This implies that the quality offered to B-types is socially optimal.
  • 68. qH is the set at the efficient level ∗ Now we will show that the chosen qH is qH —i.e. where C (qH ) = θH just like in the first order discrimination case. This implies that the quality offered to B-types is socially optimal. Suppose that the optimal qH has C (qH ) < θH .
  • 69. qH is the set at the efficient level ∗ Now we will show that the chosen qH is qH —i.e. where C (qH ) = θH just like in the first order discrimination case. This implies that the quality offered to B-types is socially optimal. Suppose that the optimal qH has C (qH ) < θH . The firm could change qH to qH + ∆, and increase pH to pH + ∆θH without violating ICH, IRH, or ICL.
  • 70. qH is the set at the efficient level ∗ Now we will show that the chosen qH is qH —i.e. where C (qH ) = θH just like in the first order discrimination case. This implies that the quality offered to B-types is socially optimal. Suppose that the optimal qH has C (qH ) < θH . The firm could change qH to qH + ∆, and increase pH to pH + ∆θH without violating ICH, IRH, or ICL. When ∆ is small, the change in the firm’s profits is approximately (1 − α)∆(θH − C (qH )) > 0.
  • 71. qH is the set at the efficient level ∗ Now we will show that the chosen qH is qH —i.e. where C (qH ) = θH just like in the first order discrimination case. This implies that the quality offered to B-types is socially optimal. Suppose that the optimal qH has C (qH ) < θH . The firm could change qH to qH + ∆, and increase pH to pH + ∆θH without violating ICH, IRH, or ICL. When ∆ is small, the change in the firm’s profits is approximately (1 − α)∆(θH − C (qH )) > 0. Thus, original qH was not optimal.
  • 72. qH is the set at the efficient level ∗ Now we will show that the chosen qH is qH —i.e. where C (qH ) = θH just like in the first order discrimination case. This implies that the quality offered to B-types is socially optimal. Suppose that the optimal qH has C (qH ) < θH . The firm could change qH to qH + ∆, and increase pH to pH + ∆θH without violating ICH, IRH, or ICL. When ∆ is small, the change in the firm’s profits is approximately (1 − α)∆(θH − C (qH )) > 0. Thus, original qH was not optimal. Similarly, if C (qH ) > θH : The firm can reduce qH to qH − ∆, provided it cuts its price for H by at least ∆θH .
  • 73. qH is the set at the efficient level ∗ Now we will show that the chosen qH is qH —i.e. where C (qH ) = θH just like in the first order discrimination case. This implies that the quality offered to B-types is socially optimal. Suppose that the optimal qH has C (qH ) < θH . The firm could change qH to qH + ∆, and increase pH to pH + ∆θH without violating ICH, IRH, or ICL. When ∆ is small, the change in the firm’s profits is approximately (1 − α)∆(θH − C (qH )) > 0. Thus, original qH was not optimal. Similarly, if C (qH ) > θH : The firm can reduce qH to qH − ∆, provided it cuts its price for H by at least ∆θH . When ∆ is small, the change in the firm’s profits is approximately ∆(C (qH ) − θH ) > 0
  • 74. Optimal prices Now we can set about characterising the optimal prices.
  • 75. Optimal prices Now we can set about characterising the optimal prices. Since IRL binds, we know that pL = θL qL .
  • 76. Optimal prices Now we can set about characterising the optimal prices. Since IRL binds, we know that pL = θL qL . Since ICH binds, we know that θH qH − pH = θH qL − pL , or ∗ equivalently, that pH = pL + θH (qH − qL ).
  • 77. Optimal prices Now we can set about characterising the optimal prices. Since IRL binds, we know that pL = θL qL . Since ICH binds, we know that θH qH − pH = θH qL − pL , or ∗ equivalently, that pH = pL + θH (qH − qL ). ∗ Combining these two statements: pH = θL qL + θH (qH − qL ).
  • 78. Firm’s objective The firm’s objective is max α(pL − C(qL )) + (1 − α)(pH − C(qH )). qL ,pL ,qH ,pH
  • 79. Firm’s objective The firm’s objective is max α(pL − C(qL )) + (1 − α)(pH − C(qH )). qL ,pL ,qH ,pH Substituting in the material we just derived (Note: since ∗ qH = qH , we only need to worry about the choice of qL .): ∗ ∗ max α(θL qL −C(qL ))+(1−α) [θL qL + θH (qH − qL ) − C(qH )] . qL
  • 80. Firm’s objective The firm’s objective is max α(pL − C(qL )) + (1 − α)(pH − C(qH )). qL ,pL ,qH ,pH Substituting in the material we just derived (Note: since ∗ qH = qH , we only need to worry about the choice of qL .): ∗ ∗ max α(θL qL −C(qL ))+(1−α) [θL qL + θH (qH − qL ) − C(qH )] . qL We can easily calculate the qL that maximises this by differentiating: α θL − C (qL ) + (1 − α) [θL − θH ] = 0
  • 81. Firm’s objective The firm’s objective is max α(pL − C(qL )) + (1 − α)(pH − C(qH )). qL ,pL ,qH ,pH Substituting in the material we just derived (Note: since ∗ qH = qH , we only need to worry about the choice of qL .): ∗ ∗ max α(θL qL −C(qL ))+(1−α) [θL qL + θH (qH − qL ) − C(qH )] . qL We can easily calculate the qL that maximises this by differentiating: α θL − C (qL ) + (1 − α) [θL − θH ] = 0 1−α Rearranging: C (qL ) = θL − α [θH − θL ]
  • 82. Firm’s objective The firm’s objective is max α(pL − C(qL )) + (1 − α)(pH − C(qH )). qL ,pL ,qH ,pH Substituting in the material we just derived (Note: since ∗ qH = qH , we only need to worry about the choice of qL .): ∗ ∗ max α(θL qL −C(qL ))+(1−α) [θL qL + θH (qH − qL ) − C(qH )] . qL We can easily calculate the qL that maximises this by differentiating: α θL − C (qL ) + (1 − α) [θL − θH ] = 0 1−α Rearranging: C (qL ) = θL − α [θH − θL ] < θL
  • 83. Discussion of the model The name of the game is to separate clients into groups and milk each group for as much as possible.
  • 84. Discussion of the model The name of the game is to separate clients into groups and milk each group for as much as possible. The monopolist can squeeze more profit from high value customers, who will pay more for a given increase in quality.
  • 85. Discussion of the model The name of the game is to separate clients into groups and milk each group for as much as possible. The monopolist can squeeze more profit from high value customers, who will pay more for a given increase in quality. But they can’t squeeze too hard—otherwise high value consumers will just buy the cheap product.
  • 86. Discussion of the model The name of the game is to separate clients into groups and milk each group for as much as possible. The monopolist can squeeze more profit from high value customers, who will pay more for a given increase in quality. But they can’t squeeze too hard—otherwise high value consumers will just buy the cheap product. Solution: deliberately degrade the usefulness of the budget product to ensure that high-value customers refuse to buy it.
  • 87. Discussion of the model The name of the game is to separate clients into groups and milk each group for as much as possible. The monopolist can squeeze more profit from high value customers, who will pay more for a given increase in quality. But they can’t squeeze too hard—otherwise high value consumers will just buy the cheap product. Solution: deliberately degrade the usefulness of the budget product to ensure that high-value customers refuse to buy it. Then the firm can charge a high price for the premium product, without worrying about customers switching to cheaper versions.
  • 88. Discussion of the model The name of the game is to separate clients into groups and milk each group for as much as possible. The monopolist can squeeze more profit from high value customers, who will pay more for a given increase in quality. But they can’t squeeze too hard—otherwise high value consumers will just buy the cheap product. Solution: deliberately degrade the usefulness of the budget product to ensure that high-value customers refuse to buy it. Then the firm can charge a high price for the premium product, without worrying about customers switching to cheaper versions.
  • 89. Examples £2/kg £2/kg £10/kg £18/kg
  • 90. Examples It is not because of the few thousand francs which would have to be spent to put a roof over the third-class carriage or to upholster the third-class seats that some company or other has open carriages with wooden benches. . . What the company is trying to do is prevent the passengers who can pay the second-class fare from travelling third class; it hits the poor, not because it wants to hurt them, but to frighten the rich. . . (Ekelund [1970])
  • 91. Note that the distortion of qL away from its optimal level is a market failure.
  • 92. Note that the distortion of qL away from its optimal level is a market failure. However, it does not follow that the optimal policy is to prevent firms from second degree discrimination. . .
  • 93. Second-degree discrimination & social welfare What will the firm do if it cannot price discriminate?
  • 94. Second-degree discrimination & social welfare What will the firm do if it cannot price discriminate? ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ Will provide either qH at price θH qH , or qL at price θL qL .
  • 95. Second-degree discrimination & social welfare What will the firm do if it cannot price discriminate? ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ Will provide either qH at price θH qH , or qL at price θL qL . In the efficient allocation, social welfare is ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ α [θL qL − C(qL )] + (1 − α) [θH qH − C(qH )] . (we can ignore the ps which simply move surplus around).
  • 96. Second-degree discrimination & social welfare What will the firm do if it cannot price discriminate? ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ Will provide either qH at price θH qH , or qL at price θL qL . In the efficient allocation, social welfare is ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ α [θL qL − C(qL )] + (1 − α) [θH qH − C(qH )] . (we can ignore the ps which simply move surplus around). In the second order price discrimination case, social welfare is ∗ ∗ α [θL qL − C(qL )] + (1 − α) [θH qH − C(qH )] .
  • 97. Second-degree discrimination & social welfare What will the firm do if it cannot price discriminate? ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ Will provide either qH at price θH qH , or qL at price θL qL . In the efficient allocation, social welfare is ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ α [θL qL − C(qL )] + (1 − α) [θH qH − C(qH )] . (we can ignore the ps which simply move surplus around). In the second order price discrimination case, social welfare is ∗ ∗ α [θL qL − C(qL )] + (1 − α) [θH qH − C(qH )] . ∗ If the firm offers only qH , social welfare is ∗ ∗ (1 − α) [θH qH − C(qH )] . Thus social welfare falls.
  • 98. Second-degree discrimination & social welfare What will the firm do if it cannot price discriminate? ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ Will provide either qH at price θH qH , or qL at price θL qL . In the efficient allocation, social welfare is ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ α [θL qL − C(qL )] + (1 − α) [θH qH − C(qH )] . (we can ignore the ps which simply move surplus around). In the second order price discrimination case, social welfare is ∗ ∗ α [θL qL − C(qL )] + (1 − α) [θH qH − C(qH )] . ∗ If the firm offers only qH , social welfare is ∗ ∗ (1 − α) [θH qH − C(qH )] . Thus social welfare falls. ∗ If the firm offers only qL , social welfare is ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ α [θL qL − C(qL )] + (1 − α) [θH qL − C(qL )] , so that welfare may fall or increase relative to second-order PD.
  • 99. More current examples In fact, when one thinks about it, there are similar-looking cases in many information markets:
  • 105. Outline Price discrimination: from assumptions to policy statements Assumptions and applicability
  • 106. Assumptions, assumptions. . . But these examples are a little different to the ones considered before: Cost to MS of “surprising” a customer by giving them the professional, rather than home edition of Windows is basically zero.
  • 107. Assumptions, assumptions. . . But these examples are a little different to the ones considered before: Cost to MS of “surprising” a customer by giving them the professional, rather than home edition of Windows is basically zero. Corresponds to C (q) = 0, C (q) = 0—which is contrary to our assumptions.
  • 108. Assumptions, assumptions. . . But these examples are a little different to the ones considered before: Cost to MS of “surprising” a customer by giving them the professional, rather than home edition of Windows is basically zero. Corresponds to C (q) = 0, C (q) = 0—which is contrary to our assumptions. When we try to put this into the model things break down. Let’s see why. . .
  • 109. Graphical treatment (assuming α = 1/2) Price Quantity Quality
  • 110. Graphical treatment (assuming α = 1/2) Price θH Quantity Quality
  • 111. Graphical treatment (assuming α = 1/2) Price Willingness to pay θH Quantity qH Quality
  • 112. Graphical treatment (assuming α = 1/2) Price C’(q) Quantity Quality
  • 113. Graphical treatment (assuming α = 1/2) Price C’(q) Cost of production Quantity qH Quality
  • 114. Graphical treatment (assuming α = 1/2) Price C’(q) θH θL Quantity Quality
  • 115. First degree discrimination Price C’(q) θH θL Quantity qL * qH * Quality
  • 116. Graphical treatment Price CS of high types from buying C’(q) low quality good θH pL θ L= qL Quantity qL qH Quality
  • 117. Graphical treatment Price CS of high types from buying C’(q) low quality good θH pL θ L= qL Quantity qL qH Quality
  • 118. Graphical treatment Price C’(q) θH pH qH pL θ L= qL Quantity qL qH Quality
  • 119. Graphical treatment Price CS of high types from buying C’(q) high quality good θH pH qH pL θ L= qL Quantity qL qH Quality
  • 120. Graphical treatment Price C’(q) θH pL θ L= qL Quantity qL qL+Δ qH Quality
  • 121. Graphical treatment Price Loss (must reduce pH to maintain ICH) C’(q) θH pL θ L= qL Quantity qL qL+Δ qH Quality
  • 122. Graphical treatment Price Loss (must reduce pH to maintain ICH) C’(q) θH pL θ L= qL Gain (can charge more to low type consumers) Loss (higher q is more expensive to produce) Quantity qL qL+Δ qH Quality
  • 123. Graphical treatment Price C’(q) θH pL θ L= qL Quantity qL qL * qH * Quality
  • 124. Constant marginal cost Price θH pL θ L= qL C’(q) Quantity Quality
  • 125. What goes wrong? Price θH pL θ L= qL C’(q) Quantity qL qL+Δ Quality
  • 126. What goes wrong? (i) Price θH pL θ L= qL C’(q) Quantity qL qL+Δ qL qL+Δ Quality
  • 127. What goes wrong? (ii) Price θH pL θ L= qL C’(q) Quantity qL qL+Δ qL qL+Δ Quality
  • 128. Declining marginal willingness to pay. Price θH C’(q) θL Quantity Quality
  • 129. Declining marginal willingness to pay. Price Declining ΔWTP θH Quantity Δq Δq Quality
  • 130. First degree descrimination. Price θH C’(q) θL Quantity qL qH Quality
  • 131. Profit effect of a quality increase. Price Loss (Need to lower pH to maintain ICH) θH Gain (Can charge more to low value consumers) C’(q) θL Quantity qL qL * qH * Quality
  • 132. Other assumptions In a similar manner, one can relax other assumptions e.g.: Oligopoly suppliers. Many consumer types. Non-continuous q.
  • 133. Summary Social science is about understanding society.
  • 134. Summary Social science is about understanding society. That, at least in part, means trying to understand the fundamental forces that drive social phenomena.
  • 135. Summary Social science is about understanding society. That, at least in part, means trying to understand the fundamental forces that drive social phenomena. Often, behaviour is fundamentally unchanged by new technology. Looking into the past can offer hints on how to understand and interpret the present.
  • 136. Summary Social science is about understanding society. That, at least in part, means trying to understand the fundamental forces that drive social phenomena. Often, behaviour is fundamentally unchanged by new technology. Looking into the past can offer hints on how to understand and interpret the present. Moreover, the result of linking related phenomena is often an insight that exceeds the sum of its parts.
  • 137. Summary Social science is about understanding society. That, at least in part, means trying to understand the fundamental forces that drive social phenomena. Often, behaviour is fundamentally unchanged by new technology. Looking into the past can offer hints on how to understand and interpret the present. Moreover, the result of linking related phenomena is often an insight that exceeds the sum of its parts. Sometimes the process works backwards: new contexts can generate insights into old puzzles—e.g. two-sided markets.
  • 138. Summary Social science is about understanding society. That, at least in part, means trying to understand the fundamental forces that drive social phenomena. Often, behaviour is fundamentally unchanged by new technology. Looking into the past can offer hints on how to understand and interpret the present. Moreover, the result of linking related phenomena is often an insight that exceeds the sum of its parts. Sometimes the process works backwards: new contexts can generate insights into old puzzles—e.g. two-sided markets. A key ingredient in making these links is an understanding of the assumptions upon which alternative conceptualisations are predicated.
  • 139. Summary Social science is about understanding society. That, at least in part, means trying to understand the fundamental forces that drive social phenomena. Often, behaviour is fundamentally unchanged by new technology. Looking into the past can offer hints on how to understand and interpret the present. Moreover, the result of linking related phenomena is often an insight that exceeds the sum of its parts. Sometimes the process works backwards: new contexts can generate insights into old puzzles—e.g. two-sided markets. A key ingredient in making these links is an understanding of the assumptions upon which alternative conceptualisations are predicated.