O slideshow foi denunciado.
Seu SlideShare está sendo baixado. ×

208 gwes unit 4d

Anúncio
Anúncio
Anúncio
Anúncio
Anúncio
Anúncio
Anúncio
Anúncio
Anúncio
Anúncio
Anúncio
Anúncio
Carregando em…3
×

Confira estes a seguir

1 de 47 Anúncio

208 gwes unit 4d

Baixar para ler offline

International Monetary System: The International Financial System - Reform of International Monetary Affairs
- The Bretton Wood System and the International Monetary Fund, Controversy over Regulation of International
Finance, Developing Countries' Concerns, Exchange Rate Policy of Developing Economies.

International Monetary System: The International Financial System - Reform of International Monetary Affairs
- The Bretton Wood System and the International Monetary Fund, Controversy over Regulation of International
Finance, Developing Countries' Concerns, Exchange Rate Policy of Developing Economies.

Anúncio
Anúncio

Mais Conteúdo rRelacionado

Diapositivos para si (20)

Semelhante a 208 gwes unit 4d (20)

Anúncio

Mais de Rakesh Bhati (20)

Mais recentes (20)

Anúncio

208 gwes unit 4d

  1. 1. Unit 4. International Monetary System 4. International Monetary System: The International Financial System - Reform of International Monetary Affairs - The Bretton Wood System and the International Monetary Fund, Controversy over Regulation of International Finance, Developing Countries' Concerns, Exchange Rate Policy of Developing Economies.
  2. 2. Developing Countries' Concerns, in three areas where further change is certainly needed: -First, the international financial architecture, where important reforms have been made, but where the hard work of implementation still lies ahead; -Second, in international financial regulation, where there is more work to do to ensure that the right incentives are in place for financial institutions in developed and developing markets to manage their risks more effectively in future; and -
  3. 3. Developing Countries' Concerns, Third, in emerging market countries themselves, where there is a need for more practical efforts to upgrade accounting and legal standards, and systems of financial regulation, and of course to clean up the balance sheets of banking systems which, in many cases, remain very fragile.
  4. 4. The main elements of that quiet revolution are: - much more outreach for banking supervisors, above all to supervisors in emerging markets; - increasing acceptance by all supervisors that core principles of supervision, rigorously applied in all countries of the world, are essential; - increasing acceptance of the need for external monitoring to ensure compliance with those core principles;
  5. 5. - a willingness by supervisors to work much more closely than before with the financial institutions as the leaders of that monitoring exercise; - greater willingness by supervisors to work more closely with each other across borders and across traditional sectors of banking, securities and insurance;
  6. 6. -a willingness by the Fund and the Bank to take on the rôle of monitoring and to integrate financial sector surveillance and reconstruction much more closely into their work; and -a desire by the international financial community to consider more carefully the threats to financial stability, to put in place better incentives for avoiding such crises, and to bring together the key government officials, supervisors, central banks and the financial institutions, through the new Financial Stability Forum.
  7. 7. Exchange Rate Policy of Developing Economies. An exchange rate, as a price of one country's money in terms of another's, is among the most important prices in an open economy. It influences the flow of goods, services, and capital in a country, and exerts strong pressure on the balance of payments, inflation and other macroeconomic variables. Therefore, the choice and management of an exchange rate regime is a critical aspect of economic management to safeguard competitiveness, macro economic stability, and growth
  8. 8. Exchange Rate Policy of Developing Economies. The choice of an appropriate exchange rate regime for developing countries has been at the center of the debate in international finance for a long time. ―What are the costs and benefits of various exchange rate regimes? ―What are the determinants of the choice of an exchange rate regime and how would country circumstances affect the choice? ― Does macroeconomic performance differ under alternative regimes? ―How would an exchange rate adjustment affect trade flows?
  9. 9. The steady increase in magnitude and variability of international capital flows has intensified the debate in the past few years as each of the major currency crises in the 1990s has in some way involved a fixed exchange rate and sudden reversal of capital inflows. New questions include: ―Are pegged regimes inherently crisis-prone? ― Which regimes would be better suited to deal with increasingly global and unstable capital markets?
  10. 10. While today almost every advanced nation has a flexible exchange rate regime similar to that advocated by Milton Friedman, most emerging countries continue to have ‘conventional peg’. Historical work of Milton Friedman examined the conditions under which he thought that flexible rates were the right system for developing countries, and when he thought that it was appropriate to have an alternative regime.
  11. 11. The currency crises in Lebanon, Turkey, and Argentina have once again brought to the fore the question of the optimal exchange rate regime in an emerging country. Almost 70 years ago, Milton Friedman published “The case for flexible exchange rates” (Friedman 1953). In it he argued that a system of ‘pegged but adjustable’ parities was highly unstable and made a strong pitch for flexible exchange rates regimes.
  12. 12. While today almost every advanced nation has a flexible exchange rate regime similar to the one advocated by Friedman, most emerging countries continue to have ‘conventional peg’ (IMF 2019). What Friedman’s views on currency and monetary regimes in developing countries were. In a 1973 Congressional testimony, Friedman said: “[w]hile I have long been in favor of a system of floating exchange rates for the major countries, I have never argued that that is necessarily also the best system for the developing countries.”
  13. 13. Milton Friedman in India: 1955 and 1963 In 1955, Milton Friedman traveled to India to advise the Nehru government. He prepared a short memorandum that covered, among other things, the exchange rate issue. At the time, foreign exchange was rationed and allocated in a discretionary fashion. Friedman wrote that there were only two ways to deal with external imbalances: “First, to inflate or deflate internally in response to a putative surplus or deficit in the balance of payments;
  14. 14. Milton Friedman in India: 1955 and 1963 second, to permit the exchange rate to fluctuate… [a method] that has been adopted by Canada with such conspicuous success” (Friedman 1955). He added that if a completely free float was ruled out (for political reasons), an auction system was a solid second-best solution. This would allow “purchasers to use it for anything they wish and in any currency area they wish.”
  15. 15. Friedman returned to India in 1965. This time he was particularly critical of the Bretton Woods’ pegged-but-adjustable regime. A mere devaluation, he stated, was not a solution in a country with chronic inflation. In a lecture delivered in Mumbai he said: “The temptation will be to change its [the rupee’s] value from its present level… and then try to hold it at the new fixed level. That would be another mistake. Even if the new exchange rates are correct when established, once you pegged them, there is no assurance that they will indefinitely remain correct” (Friedman 1968).
  16. 16. The ten regimes are arranged under the following four relatively homogeneous groups (a) Floating regimes (independent floating, lightly managed float); (b) Intermediate regimes (managed float, crawling broad band); (c) Soft peg reglmes (crawling narrow band, crawling peg, pegged within bands, fixed peg); and (d) Hard peg regimes (currency board, currency union/dollarization).
  17. 17. The floating regimes would be an appropriate choice for medium and large industrialized countries and some emerging market economies that have import and export sectors that are relatively small compared to GDP, but are fully integrated in the global capital markets and have diversified production and trade, a deep and broad financial sector, and strong prudential standards. The hard peg regimes are more appropriate for countries satisfying the optimum currency area criteria (countries in the European Economic and Monetary Union), small countries already integrated in a larger neighboring country (dollarization in Panama), or countries with a history of monetary disorder, high inflation, and low credibility of policymakers to maintain stability that need a strong anchor for monetary stabilization (currency board in Argentina and Bulgaria).
  18. 18. The soft peg regimes would be best for countries with limited links to international capital markets, less diversified production and exports, and shallow financial markets, as well as countries stabilizing from high and protracted inflation under an exchange rate-based stabilization program (Turkey). These are largely but not exclusively non emerging market developing countries . The intermediate regimes, a middle road between floating rates and soft pegs, aim to incorporate the benefits of floating and pegged regimes while avoiding their shortcomings.
  19. 19. The macroeconomic authorities of developing and transition countries are faced with a difficult task. On the one hand, the global economy is unstable with frequent shocks, crises and volatilities. It is also a place with fierce competition with multinational corporations of EU, US, Japan and Korea, the emergence of China as the factory of the world, dumping and unfair trade practices by some exporters, etc. On the other hand, the domestic capability of most developing and transition countries is still weak. The market economy is not well developed, and domestic enterprises lack competitiveness. The government is often saddled with inefficiency, corruption, lack of expertise, and political pressure.
  20. 20. The question for the central bank governor and the finance minister is: how do you manage monetary policy, and especially the exchange rate, in order to avoid unnecessary shocks and provide stable environment for economic development? More specifically, in this age of accelerated globalization, what is the appropriate exchange rate system for developing or transition countries? The question is difficult enough, but to make the matter even more complicated, there are many policy goals but only one exchange rate.
  21. 21. If a country has the multiple exchange rate system, the IMF will not seriously deal with you and FDI will probably not come. It is a good idea to unify the rates as soon as possible. China unified their rates in 1994 and Vietnam did so in 1989. Unification did not give them any big shock, and they began to receive large amounts of FDI after that, partly because of the improved exchange rate system.
  22. 22. The government is often concerned about the social consequences of currency reunification, but people are usually much better off with a unified rate than without. The persistence of the multiple exchange rate practice is mainly a political problem, not economic. It is a huge and hidden subsidy and taxation system, from which some people benefit greatly.
  23. 23. The possible goals for exchange rate management may include the following: 1. Competitiveness 2. Price stability 3. Current account adjustment 4. Domestic financial stability (protection of balance sheets of banks and firms) 5. Public debt management 6. Avoiding speculative attacks 7. Minimizing domestic impact of a large exogenous shock (like a regional conflict or currency crisis) 8. Promoting FDI, growth, or industrialization
  24. 24. The first two goals--competitiveness and price stability--are very fundamental and all countries should mind them. The big problem is that these two goals often conflict with each other. To maintain competitiveness (or regain it after domestic inflation), the exchange rate should be flexible and devaluation must be accepted, if necessary.
  25. 25. On the other hand, to contain domestic inflation or avoid imported inflation, the exchange rate should be either stable or even moderately overvalued (this is called the use of the exchange rate as a nominal anchor). But clearly, these two requirements are not compatible. it keeps the exchange rate stable, it will exert a deflationary pressure on the domestic economy so the inflation- devaluation spiral can be avoided. But in this case, competitiveness is lost due to overvaluation, and a recession is likely.
  26. 26. The third goal--current account adjustment--is popular but controversial. Traditionally, devaluation is recommended to a country with a current account (or trade) deficit. However, whether it really works to reduce the deficit or not must be carefully studied in the context of each individual country. Devaluation is a double-edged sword; as noted above, it may trigger an inflation spiral. It may also affect the macroeconomy in other complicated ways to offset the intended relative-price effect
  27. 27. The fourth and fifth goals--protecting the balance sheets of the private and public sectors--are related to the question of exchange exposure and losses. If the currency is devalued, the value of foreign currency-denominated debt will increase in home currency, which creates enormous difficulties for both the private and public sectors. Part of this debt can be hedged, but not all
  28. 28. The sixth goal--avoiding speculative attacks--can be achieved by calming the market expectation. How can we do this? Some economists argue that the exchange rate should float. Exchange rate flexibility will remind traders that the currency can go both up as well as down, which discourages them from betting on exchange rate stability or one-way movement. This makes attacks less likely. But exchange rate volatility itself may become a problem. Perhaps the best way to avoid attacks is to avoid overvaluation, and that is attained by frequent reviews and proper adjustments of the exchange rate levels (i.e., fulfilling the competitiveness concern).
  29. 29. The seventh goal--minimizing impact of a large external crisis--essentially is the question of the timing and manner of floating. If the currency of an important neighboring country collapses, your currency becomes suddenly overvalued, relatively speaking. The government must decide whether the home currency should (partly) follow this depreciation or remain stable. There is no easy rule of thumb as to whether you should float earlier, later, or not at all; it depends on individual cases.
  30. 30. The eighth goal--promoting FDI, growth, or industrialization--is, in my view, a red herring. Such long-term real-sector development goals cannot be pursued by exchange rate management. The only thing that the central bank can do for this purpose is to maintain competitiveness and price stability (namely, doing well in the first two goals).
  31. 31. Managed float After the Mexican (1994) and the Asian (1997) crises, many economists began to argue that dollar peg was dangerous. They contend that exchange rates should be flexible enough so adjustments are not delayed until too late. Some even argue that IMF should not lend to countries with a dollar peg !
  32. 32. Bipolar view Some economists--Barry Eichengreen, Stanley Fischer and others--went even further. According to them, the reality of the 21st century with massive financial flows would not allow any country to adopt a "middle" solution such as target zones, adjustable peg, baskets, crawling peg, etc. They recommend that all countries, including developing and transition ones, to converge on either complete fix or 100% free floating.
  33. 33. Currency board The currency board is an institutional arrangement to tie money supply closely to the amount of international reserves, so the monetary authority has no power to issue money independently (in principle, at least). In the most rigid case, monetary base can be issued or withdrawn only in exchange with foreign assets sold or bought against the monetary authority (however, most currency boards are not so rigid; there are loopholes and lee ways). With a currency board, monetary policy is not needed so the central bank is abolished and a simpler "monetary authority" takes over.
  34. 34. Dollarization dollarization has two meanings. Private (or inadvertent) dollarization: people use dollars because they do not trust domestic money or foreign money is more convenient than domestic money. Official dollarization: the government declares USD to be the only official money for the country, and abolishes domestic money.
  35. 35. Multiple currency basket (proposed for East Asia) multiple currency baskets consisting of dollar, yen and euro are recommended by some economists to the developing countries in East Asia. These baskets are supposed to automatically smooth the competitiveness shocks arising from the movements of major currencies (but they do not automatically adjust for other shocks
  36. 36. Soft dollar zone (for East Asia) Ronald McKinnon argues that neither floating nor the currency basket is practical in East Asia. He notes that East Asian currencies actually returned to the soft dollar peg after the Asian crisis, the situation which he thinks is desirable and reasonable. The dollar is the key currency in the world economy and monetary stability should be built around it.
  37. 37. Virtual exchange rate stability This is also proposed by Prof. McKinnon (especially for major countries). There should be a long-term, unchanging nominal exchange rate target based on tradable PPP (for example, $1=110 yen). The two countries (for example, Japan and the US) have the obligation to keep the rate within the narrow band around this target forever. When a large shock hits occasionally (once in a decade?), the rate can deviate temporarily from the target. But after the shock is gone, the rate must return to the original, unchanged band.
  38. 38. Double target zones John Williamson (Institute of International Economics, Washington DC) is the champion of target zone proposals. He has many ideas, and the double target zone is one of them. There should be a "soft" inner band and a "hard" outer band, so the central bank will have three zones where (i) it does not intervene; (ii) it can intervene; and (iii) it must intervene.
  39. 39. Band-basket-crawl (BBC) This idea, advanced by Rudiger Dornbusch and Y. C. Park, is a variation of the target zone proposal. The central rate should be defined by a multiple currency basket and there should be a band around it. Moreover, there is a built-in inflation sliding of the central rate. This is what I would call a currency basket with inflation slide.
  40. 40. "Eclectic" view Jeffrey Frankel wrote a paper entitled: "No single currency regime is right for all countries or at all times." The right choice depends on circumstances, and each country should adopt the most suitable system for itself. The attempt to find a one- size-fits-all solution is misguided.

×