SlideShare uma empresa Scribd logo
1 de 23
Baixar para ler offline
This	
  video	
  clip	
  reviews	
  the	
  microeconomic	
  concepts	
  that	
  we’ll	
  be	
  using	
  in	
  our	
  course.	
  
-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐	
  Mee:ng	
  Notes	
  (1/22/12	
  08:53)	
  -­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐	
  
In	
  our	
  interna:onal	
  economics	
  course.	
  




                                                                                                                                   1	
  
The	
  review	
  includes	
  two	
  items:	
  (1)	
  the	
  mechanics	
  of	
  the	
  simple	
  model	
  of	
  a	
  
compe::ve	
  market	
  that	
  economists	
  use	
  and	
  (2)	
  the	
  underpinnings	
  of	
  the	
  
conven:onal	
  choice	
  theory	
  –	
  both	
  collec:ve	
  and	
  individual.	
  	
  	
  




                                                                                                                       2	
  
First	
  off,	
  what	
  is	
  a	
  market?	
  	
  	
  
	
  
For	
  our	
  purposes	
  here,	
  we’ll	
  view	
  a	
  market	
  as	
  a	
  bunch	
  of	
  people	
  trading	
  a	
  good	
  on	
  a	
  
voluntary	
  basis.	
  	
  The	
  good	
  defines	
  the	
  market.	
  	
  If	
  the	
  good	
  is	
  oranges,	
  then	
  it	
  is	
  a	
  
market	
  for	
  oranges.	
  	
  	
  
	
  
Markets	
  are	
  social	
  structures	
  –	
  people	
  rela:ng	
  to	
  one	
  another	
  in	
  certain	
  ways	
  (in	
  this	
  
case,	
  acknowledging	
  and	
  respec:ng	
  their	
  mutual	
  property	
  and	
  coopera:ng	
  with	
  one	
  
another	
  via	
  trade).	
  	
  For	
  more	
  on	
  this,	
  see	
  my	
  slides	
  on	
  Coopera:on	
  &	
  Social	
  
Structures.	
  
	
  
At	
  this	
  point,	
  we	
  make	
  the	
  assump:on	
  that	
  this	
  market	
  is	
  compe::ve.	
  	
  By	
  this	
  we	
  
mean,	
  first,	
  that	
  the	
  good	
  is	
  homogeneous.	
  	
  There	
  are	
  no	
  differences	
  in	
  the	
  quality	
  or	
  
characteris:cs	
  of	
  the	
  good.	
  	
  Say	
  it	
  is	
  oranges.	
  	
  They	
  are	
  generic	
  oranges.	
  	
  For	
  a	
  buyer,	
  
it	
  doesn’t	
  maVer	
  who	
  supplies	
  the	
  oranges,	
  because	
  they	
  all	
  look	
  and	
  taste	
  and	
  smell	
  
the	
  same.	
  	
  And	
  second,	
  to	
  say	
  that	
  the	
  market	
  is	
  compe::ve	
  is	
  to	
  say	
  that	
  there	
  are	
  
many	
  buyers	
  and	
  many	
  sellers,	
  so	
  no	
  par:cular	
  buyer	
  or	
  seller	
  has	
  “market	
  power”	
  –	
  
i.e.	
  the	
  ability	
  to	
  manipulate	
  the	
  price	
  individually.	
  	
  And	
  since	
  there	
  are	
  many	
  and	
  the	
  
good	
  is	
  the	
  same,	
  the	
  sellers	
  cannot	
  differen:ate	
  the	
  good	
  or	
  form	
  coali:ons.	
  	
  
Neither	
  can	
  the	
  buyers.	
  	
  Basically,	
  it’s	
  just	
  a	
  bunch	
  of	
  individual	
  buyers	
  and	
  sellers	
  
trying	
  to	
  do	
  the	
  best	
  they	
  can	
  for	
  each	
  of	
  them	
  individually	
  without	
  regard	
  for	
  the	
  	
  




                                                                                                                                                  3	
  
We	
  split	
  the	
  people	
  into	
  two	
  groups	
  –	
  one	
  group,	
  we	
  call	
  the	
  buyers.	
  	
  These	
  people	
  
have	
  money	
  and	
  want	
  the	
  good.	
  	
  The	
  second	
  group	
  is	
  the	
  sellers.	
  	
  These	
  people	
  have	
  
the	
  good,	
  but	
  they	
  want	
  the	
  money.	
  	
  The	
  two	
  groups	
  meet	
  and	
  make	
  the	
  market	
  by	
  
nego:a:ng	
  prices	
  at	
  which	
  they	
  are	
  willing	
  to	
  trade.	
  	
  There	
  will	
  be	
  a	
  single	
  price	
  in	
  
this	
  market,	
  at	
  which	
  all	
  buyers	
  will	
  buy	
  the	
  good	
  and	
  all	
  sellers	
  will	
  sell	
  the	
  good.	
  	
  
Once	
  the	
  two	
  groups	
  agree	
  on	
  a	
  price	
  such	
  that	
  the	
  buyers	
  want	
  to	
  buy	
  the	
  same	
  
amount	
  of	
  the	
  good	
  that	
  the	
  sellers	
  wish	
  to	
  sell	
  –	
  and	
  we	
  call	
  that	
  the	
  “market	
  
equilibrium”	
  –	
  the	
  deal	
  is	
  made,	
  they	
  shake	
  hands,	
  sellers	
  hand	
  the	
  good	
  to	
  the	
  
buyers,	
  buyers	
  pay	
  the	
  sellers	
  the	
  money,	
  and	
  each	
  group	
  goes	
  home	
  happier	
  or	
  at	
  
least	
  not	
  less	
  happy	
  than	
  they	
  were	
  before.	
  	
  Remember:	
  it	
  is	
  a	
  voluntary	
  transac:on.	
  	
  
If	
  people	
  felt	
  that	
  trading	
  made	
  them	
  less	
  happy,	
  then	
  why	
  would	
  they	
  do	
  it	
  
voluntarily?	
  
	
  
We	
  construct	
  the	
  model	
  in	
  the	
  following	
  way:	
  First,	
  we	
  study	
  the	
  behavior	
  of	
  buyers.	
  	
  
We	
  call	
  that	
  the	
  demand	
  side.	
  	
  Second,	
  we	
  study	
  the	
  behavior	
  of	
  the	
  sellers.	
  	
  We	
  call	
  
that	
  the	
  supply	
  side.	
  	
  Third,	
  we	
  put	
  the	
  two	
  together.	
  	
  We	
  call	
  that	
  equilibrium.	
  	
  
Fourth,	
  we	
  study	
  how	
  equilibrium	
  is	
  aVained.	
  	
  Fi]h,	
  we	
  shock	
  the	
  model	
  by	
  making	
  
some	
  or	
  other	
  factor	
  (other	
  than	
  price)	
  affect	
  the	
  behavior	
  of	
  buyers	
  or	
  sellers	
  or	
  
both,	
  and	
  see	
  what	
  the	
  model	
  predicts.	
  	
  This	
  is	
  the	
  way	
  in	
  which	
  we	
  test	
  the	
  model.	
  	
  
If	
  the	
  predic:ons	
  of	
  the	
  model	
  match	
  what	
  we	
  observe	
  in	
  reality,	
  then	
  –	
  and	
  to	
  that	
  
extent	
  –	
  we	
  deem	
  the	
  model	
  as	
  reliable	
  and	
  use	
  it	
  in	
  our	
  prac:cal	
  applica:ons.	
  	
  	
  




                                                                                                                                                 4	
  
Demand.	
  
	
  
The	
  ques:on	
  we	
  pose	
  here	
  is:	
  What	
  makes	
  buyers	
  buy	
  more	
  (or	
  less)	
  of	
  a	
  good?	
  	
  
There	
  are	
  many	
  factors.	
  	
  Let	
  me	
  limit	
  my	
  list	
  to	
  a	
  few	
  of	
  these	
  factors:	
  	
  
	
  
Price	
  is	
  the	
  first	
  one.	
  	
  And	
  in	
  the	
  graphic	
  model	
  that	
  we	
  use,	
  this	
  is	
  the	
  variable	
  that	
  is	
  
explicitly	
  included	
  in	
  the	
  analysis.	
  	
  Economists	
  say	
  that	
  this	
  variable,	
  price,	
  and	
  the	
  
quan:ty	
  traded	
  (demanded	
  and	
  supplied)	
  are	
  the	
  *endogenous*	
  variables.	
  	
  Other	
  
variables,	
  which	
  are	
  not	
  explicitly	
  visible	
  in	
  the	
  analysis,	
  are	
  called	
  *exogenous*.	
  	
  It	
  
doesn’t	
  mean	
  that	
  we	
  don’t	
  care	
  about	
  them.	
  	
  We	
  have	
  ways	
  to	
  reflect	
  the	
  impact	
  of	
  
changes	
  on	
  those	
  variables	
  on	
  our	
  market	
  model	
  –	
  on	
  price	
  and	
  quan:ty.	
  	
  But	
  our	
  
liVle	
  model	
  cannot	
  explain	
  *why*	
  they	
  change.	
  	
  We	
  are	
  just	
  going	
  to	
  assume,	
  
whenever	
  we	
  may	
  deem	
  that	
  convenient,	
  that	
  these	
  variables	
  change	
  and	
  then	
  
register	
  the	
  effect	
  of	
  those	
  changes	
  on	
  price	
  and	
  quan:ty.	
  
	
  
Price	
  maVers	
  here,	
  because	
  –	
  and	
  this	
  seems	
  like	
  a	
  reasonable	
  assump:on	
  to	
  make,	
  
since	
  it	
  appears	
  to	
  match	
  what	
  we	
  observe	
  in	
  the	
  world	
  –	
  if	
  the	
  price	
  is	
  higher,	
  buyers	
  
will	
  tend	
  to	
  buy	
  less	
  of	
  the	
  good.	
  	
  If,	
  on	
  the	
  other	
  hand,	
  the	
  price	
  is	
  lower,	
  buyers	
  will	
  
tend	
  to	
  buy	
  more.	
  	
  So,	
  there’s	
  a	
  nega:ve	
  or	
  inverse	
  rela:onship	
  between	
  price	
  and	
  
quan:ty	
  demanded	
  –	
  the	
  quan:ty	
  that	
  buyers	
  wish	
  to	
  buy	
  given	
  all	
  other	
  things.	
  
	
  




                                                                                                                                                          5	
  
Here’s	
  the	
  graph	
  of	
  the	
  demand	
  rela:onship.	
  	
  	
  	
  
	
  
This	
  graph	
  (the	
  curve	
  or	
  line)	
  shows	
  directly	
  the	
  rela:onship	
  between	
  the	
  quan:ty	
  
demanded	
  for	
  the	
  good	
  and	
  the	
  price	
  of	
  the	
  good.	
  	
  It	
  is	
  a	
  nega:ve	
  rela:onship.	
  	
  That	
  
is	
  why	
  the	
  slope	
  of	
  the	
  line	
  is	
  nega:ve.	
  	
  The	
  line	
  is	
  downward	
  sloping.	
  	
  Now,	
  for	
  
simplicity,	
  I’m	
  drawing	
  it	
  as	
  a	
  straight	
  line.	
  	
  Real	
  demand	
  lines,	
  if	
  we	
  are	
  able	
  to	
  
es:mate	
  them	
  (and	
  there	
  are	
  difficul:es	
  to	
  es:mate	
  them	
  empirically),	
  don’t	
  need	
  to	
  
be	
  straight	
  lines.	
  	
  This	
  is	
  a	
  simplifica:on,	
  but	
  it	
  is	
  a	
  simplifica:on	
  that	
  helps	
  us	
  clarify	
  
things	
  nicely.	
  
	
  
Note	
  that	
  in	
  this	
  graph,	
  we	
  can	
  only	
  show	
  two	
  variables	
  explicitly	
  or	
  directly.	
  	
  As	
  I	
  
said,	
  the	
  two	
  variables	
  we	
  care	
  most	
  about	
  are	
  the	
  price	
  and	
  the	
  quan:ty	
  traded.	
  	
  So	
  
the	
  graph	
  only	
  shows	
  the	
  link	
  between	
  price	
  and	
  quan:ty	
  explicitly.	
  	
  	
  When	
  we	
  
consider	
  the	
  change	
  in	
  the	
  price	
  of	
  the	
  good	
  and	
  then	
  the	
  reac:on	
  of	
  buyers,	
  then	
  we	
  
say	
  that	
  we	
  are	
  “moving	
  along”	
  the	
  demand	
  line	
  or	
  demand	
  curve.	
  	
  	
  
	
  
Let	
  me	
  note	
  that	
  we	
  are	
  drawing	
  the	
  demand	
  curve	
  as	
  a	
  straight	
  line	
  for	
  convenience	
  
only.	
  	
  There	
  is	
  no	
  reason	
  why	
  an	
  actual	
  demand	
  curve	
  would	
  be	
  linear.	
  	
  




                                                                                                                                                 6	
  
When	
  other	
  factors	
  (not	
  explicitly	
  indicated	
  -­‐-­‐	
  the	
  factors	
  that	
  we	
  listed	
  before:	
  
income,	
  tastes,	
  other	
  prices,	
  expecta:ons)…	
  when	
  those	
  factors	
  change,	
  that	
  has	
  an	
  
effect	
  on	
  the	
  whole	
  demand	
  line.	
  	
  	
  The	
  demand	
  line	
  shi]s.	
  	
  For	
  example,	
  suppose	
  that	
  
this	
  is	
  the	
  market	
  for	
  oranges	
  and	
  the	
  price	
  of	
  apples	
  increases.	
  	
  Then,	
  as	
  a	
  result,	
  the	
  
en:re	
  demand	
  line	
  for	
  oranges	
  may	
  shi]	
  to	
  the	
  right	
  –	
  indica:ng	
  that	
  for	
  each	
  given	
  
price,	
  buyers	
  are	
  willing	
  to	
  buy	
  more	
  oranges	
  due	
  to	
  the	
  higher	
  price	
  of	
  apples.	
  	
  This	
  
is	
  called	
  a	
  rightward	
  *shi]*	
  of	
  the	
  demand	
  line.	
  	
  It	
  is	
  easy	
  to	
  see	
  that	
  the	
  effect	
  of	
  
changes	
  in	
  the	
  other	
  variables	
  listed	
  (variables	
  other	
  than	
  price	
  and	
  the	
  quan:ty	
  
demanded)	
  can	
  be	
  shown	
  in	
  this	
  graph	
  as	
  a	
  shi]	
  of	
  the	
  demand	
  line.	
  
	
  
Now,	
  just	
  by	
  looking	
  at	
  the	
  shi]	
  in	
  the	
  diagram,	
  we	
  may	
  not	
  be	
  able	
  to	
  know	
  what	
  
cause	
  that	
  shi].	
  	
  So,	
  we’ll	
  need	
  to	
  add	
  separate	
  informa:on	
  to	
  our	
  diagram	
  so	
  that	
  
we	
  know	
  why	
  the	
  graph,	
  the	
  demand	
  line	
  shi]ed.	
  




                                                                                                                                                   7	
  
Let	
  us	
  now	
  consider	
  …	
  supply.	
  	
  This	
  is	
  the	
  descrip:on	
  of	
  how	
  the	
  sellers	
  (the	
  other	
  
side	
  of	
  the	
  market)	
  behave.	
  
	
  
The	
  ques:on	
  here	
  is:	
  What	
  makes	
  sellers	
  sell	
  more	
  (or	
  less)	
  of	
  a	
  good?	
  	
  There	
  are	
  also	
  
many	
  factors.	
  	
  These	
  are	
  a	
  few	
  important	
  ones:	
  	
  
	
  
Price	
  is,	
  again,	
  the	
  first	
  one.	
  	
  The	
  higher	
  the	
  price,	
  the	
  more	
  of	
  the	
  good	
  the	
  sellers	
  
would	
  want	
  to	
  sell,	
  other	
  things	
  equal.	
  
	
  
Suppose	
  that	
  the	
  producers	
  and,	
  more	
  generally,	
  the	
  sellers	
  of	
  the	
  good	
  are	
  business	
  
people.	
  	
  They	
  are	
  offering	
  the	
  good	
  for	
  sale,	
  because	
  they	
  want	
  to	
  make	
  a	
  profit.	
  The	
  
profit	
  they	
  obtain	
  per	
  unit	
  of	
  the	
  good	
  is	
  the	
  difference	
  between	
  the	
  price	
  of	
  the	
  
good	
  and	
  the	
  cost	
  of	
  the	
  good	
  for	
  them.	
  	
  Let	
  us	
  define	
  here	
  the	
  cost	
  of	
  the	
  good	
  as	
  
the	
  minimum	
  price	
  at	
  which	
  the	
  sellers	
  are	
  willing	
  to	
  sell	
  the	
  good.	
  	
  Clearly,	
  if	
  the	
  cost	
  
of	
  the	
  good	
  is	
  given,	
  the	
  higher	
  the	
  price,	
  the	
  higher	
  their	
  profit.	
  	
  On	
  the	
  other	
  hand,	
  
if	
  the	
  price	
  of	
  the	
  good	
  is	
  given,	
  then	
  the	
  lower	
  the	
  cost	
  of	
  the	
  good,	
  the	
  higher	
  the	
  
profit.	
  
	
  
Given	
  the	
  price	
  of	
  the	
  good,	
  its	
  cost	
  is	
  going	
  to	
  be	
  their	
  main	
  considera:on	
  when	
  
deciding	
  how	
  much	
  of	
  the	
  good	
  to	
  sell.	
  	
  What	
  is	
  the	
  cost:	
  Well,	
  if	
  they	
  are	
  the	
  
producers,	
  they	
  need	
  to	
  assemble	
  the	
  inputs	
  required	
  to	
  produce	
  the	
  good	
  and	
  pay	
  	
  




                                                                                                                                                    8	
  
Here’s	
  the	
  graph	
  of	
  the	
  supply	
  rela:onship.	
  	
  	
  	
  
	
  
This	
  graph	
  (the	
  curve	
  or	
  line)	
  shows	
  directly	
  the	
  rela:onship	
  between	
  the	
  quan:ty	
  
supplied	
  of	
  the	
  good	
  and	
  the	
  price	
  of	
  the	
  good.	
  	
  It	
  is	
  a	
  posi:ve	
  rela:onship.	
  The	
  
supply	
  curve	
  or	
  line	
  is	
  upward	
  sloping.	
  	
  For	
  simplicity,	
  I	
  draw	
  it	
  as	
  a	
  straight	
  line.	
  	
  Real	
  
supply	
  lines,	
  also	
  hard	
  to	
  es:mate	
  empirically,	
  don’t	
  need	
  to	
  be	
  straight	
  lines.	
  	
  But	
  we	
  
are	
  simplifying	
  maVers.	
  
	
  
You	
  will	
  note	
  that	
  the	
  supply	
  curve	
  here	
  is	
  also	
  a	
  straight	
  line,	
  just	
  like	
  the	
  demand	
  
curve	
  was	
  a	
  straight	
  line.	
  	
  Again,	
  this	
  is	
  for	
  convenience	
  only.	
  	
  There	
  is	
  no	
  reason	
  why	
  
an	
  actual	
  demand	
  or	
  supply	
  curves	
  would	
  be	
  linear.	
  	
  
	
  
Now,	
  again,	
  if	
  we	
  are	
  studying	
  the	
  change	
  in	
  the	
  price	
  of	
  the	
  good	
  and	
  how	
  sellers	
  
react	
  to	
  it,	
  we	
  are	
  “moving	
  along”	
  the	
  supply	
  curve.	
  	
  	
  




                                                                                                                                                         9	
  
When	
  the	
  other	
  factors	
  change,	
  the	
  supply	
  curve	
  shi]s	
  en:rely.	
  	
  Suppose	
  that	
  this	
  is	
  
the	
  market	
  for	
  oranges	
  and	
  the	
  price	
  of	
  labor	
  decreases	
  (say,	
  there	
  is	
  high	
  
unemployment	
  in	
  the	
  area	
  and	
  workers	
  have	
  to	
  accept	
  lower	
  wages).	
  	
  Then,	
  as	
  a	
  
result,	
  the	
  en:re	
  supply	
  curve	
  to	
  the	
  right	
  –	
  indica:ng	
  that	
  for	
  each	
  given	
  price,	
  
sellers	
  are	
  willing	
  to	
  sell	
  more	
  oranges	
  due	
  to	
  the	
  lower	
  cost	
  of	
  labor.	
  	
  This	
  is	
  called	
  a	
  
rightward	
  *shi]*	
  of	
  the	
  supply	
  curve.	
  	
  	
  
	
  
And	
  when	
  any	
  of	
  the	
  other	
  factors	
  may	
  change,	
  we	
  can	
  do	
  something	
  similar	
  to	
  
register	
  that	
  change	
  and	
  its	
  effect	
  on	
  the	
  market	
  in	
  our	
  diagram.	
  




                                                                                                                                                       10	
  
We	
  are	
  now	
  ready	
  to	
  put	
  the	
  demand	
  and	
  the	
  supply	
  sides	
  together.	
  	
  In	
  the	
  diagram,	
  
we	
  show	
  now	
  the	
  demand	
  and	
  the	
  supply	
  curves.	
  	
  Demand	
  is	
  downward	
  sloping.	
  	
  
Supply	
  is	
  upward	
  sloping.	
  	
  As	
  a	
  result,	
  they	
  cross	
  at	
  a	
  point.	
  	
  Let	
  us	
  examine	
  the	
  point	
  
where	
  they	
  cross.	
  
	
  
The	
  demand	
  curve	
  shows	
  the	
  different	
  quan::es	
  of	
  the	
  good	
  that	
  buyers	
  wish	
  to	
  buy	
  
at	
  different	
  prices	
  (given	
  the	
  economic	
  environment).	
  	
  The	
  supply	
  curve	
  shows	
  the	
  
different	
  quan::es	
  of	
  the	
  good	
  that	
  sellers	
  wish	
  to	
  sell	
  at	
  different	
  prices	
  (again,	
  
given	
  the	
  economic	
  environment).	
  	
  The	
  point	
  where	
  the	
  two	
  curves	
  cross	
  is	
  a	
  price	
  
and	
  a	
  quan:ty	
  –	
  the	
  price	
  at	
  which	
  the	
  quan:ty	
  demand	
  and	
  the	
  quan:ty	
  supplied	
  
are	
  equal.	
  
	
  
At	
  this	
  price,	
  buyers	
  and	
  sellers	
  agree	
  on	
  the	
  quan:ty	
  they	
  wish	
  to	
  trade.	
  	
  We	
  call	
  it	
  
equilibrium,	
  because	
  if	
  nothing	
  changes	
  in	
  the	
  economic	
  environment,	
  then	
  there	
  is	
  
no	
  reason	
  why	
  buyers	
  or	
  sellers	
  may	
  want	
  to	
  be	
  somewhere	
  else	
  rather	
  than	
  at	
  that	
  
point.	
  
	
  
Consider	
  the	
  case	
  where	
  the	
  price	
  is	
  higher	
  than	
  the	
  equilibrium	
  price	
  –	
  say	
  about	
  
here.	
  	
  Note	
  then	
  that	
  the	
  quan:ty	
  that	
  buyers	
  want	
  to	
  buy	
  falls	
  short	
  of	
  the	
  quan:ty	
  
that	
  sellers	
  want	
  to	
  sell.	
  	
  As	
  a	
  consequence,	
  there	
  is	
  no	
  deal.	
  	
  There	
  is	
  a	
  gap	
  between	
  
the	
  quan:ty	
  demanded	
  and	
  the	
  quan:ty	
  supplied.	
  	
  Economists	
  call	
  that	
  gap	
  a	
  glut.	
  	
  It	
  	
  




                                                                                                                                                     11	
  
Let	
  us	
  now	
  do	
  the	
  algebra.	
  
	
  
The	
  demand	
  equa:on	
  is	
  this	
  one:	
  P	
  =	
  12	
  -­‐	
  .8	
  Qd	
  
	
  
     where	
  12	
  is	
  the	
  ver:cal	
  intercept	
  and	
  -­‐0.8	
  is	
  the	
  slope.	
  
     	
  
     The	
  intercept	
  or	
  any	
  price	
  above	
  it	
  would	
  discourage	
  buyers	
  from	
  buying	
  the	
  good.	
  	
  
     No	
  buyer	
  would	
  pay	
  that	
  much	
  for	
  the	
  good.	
  The	
  slope	
  (.8)	
  indicates	
  the	
  drop	
  in	
  the	
  
     price	
  that	
  would	
  make	
  buyers	
  buy	
  one	
  extra	
  unit	
  of	
  the	
  good.	
  
     	
  
     Note	
  that	
  the	
  ver:cal	
  axis	
  shows	
  you	
  how	
  much	
  the	
  buyers	
  value	
  one	
  unit	
  of	
  the	
  
     good.	
  	
  It	
  indicates	
  how	
  much	
  they	
  benefit	
  from	
  it,	
  since	
  they	
  would	
  only	
  pay	
  the	
  
     price	
  for	
  it	
  if	
  they	
  felt	
  that	
  the	
  benefit	
  received	
  compensates	
  them	
  properly.	
  
	
  
	
  
	
  
	
  




                                                                                                                                               12	
  
And	
  here	
  is	
  the	
  supply	
  equa:on:	
  P	
  =	
  2	
  +	
  .2	
  Qs,	
  where	
  2	
  is	
  the	
  ver:cal	
  intercept	
  and	
  
0.25	
  is	
  the	
  slope.	
  
	
  
At	
  the	
  intercept	
  or	
  any	
  price	
  below	
  it,	
  no	
  seller	
  would	
  sell	
  any	
  of	
  the	
  good.	
  	
  The	
  slope	
  
indicates	
  the	
  increase	
  in	
  the	
  price	
  that	
  would	
  lead	
  sellers	
  to	
  sell	
  one	
  extra	
  unit	
  of	
  the	
  
good.	
  
	
  
It	
  is	
  important	
  to	
  note	
  here	
  that	
  the	
  ver:cal	
  axis	
  also	
  shows	
  how	
  much	
  the	
  sellers	
  
value	
  the	
  good.	
  	
  It	
  indicates	
  how	
  much	
  the	
  good	
  costs	
  the	
  sellers,	
  since	
  they	
  would	
  
only	
  sell	
  it	
  if	
  they	
  feel	
  compensated	
  for	
  such	
  cost.	
  
	
  




                                                                                                                                                     13	
  
We	
  have	
  a	
  system	
  of	
  two	
  linear	
  equa:ons.	
  	
  The	
  demand	
  has	
  to	
  sa:sfy	
  the	
  rule	
  P	
  =	
  12	
  
-­‐	
  .8	
  Qd	
  and	
  the	
  supply	
  the	
  rule	
  that	
  P	
  =	
  2	
  +	
  .2	
  Qs.	
  	
  In	
  equilibrium,	
  the	
  price	
  that	
  buyers	
  
pay	
  is	
  the	
  same	
  price	
  that	
  the	
  sellers	
  receive.	
  	
  And	
  the	
  quan:ty	
  that	
  the	
  buyers	
  want	
  
to	
  buy	
  is	
  the	
  quan:ty	
  that	
  the	
  sellers	
  want	
  to	
  sell.	
  	
  In	
  other	
  words,	
  the	
  equilibrium	
  
price	
  and	
  quan:ty	
  are	
  the	
  values	
  of	
  P	
  and	
  Q	
  that	
  solve	
  the	
  two	
  equa:ons	
  
simultaneously.	
  
	
  
Let	
  us	
  solve	
  the	
  system	
  algebraically	
  now.	
  	
  Since	
  the	
  price	
  has	
  to	
  be	
  the	
  same	
  for	
  
both	
  buyers	
  and	
  sellers,	
  then	
  we	
  can	
  make	
  the	
  RHS	
  of	
  these	
  equa:ons	
  equal	
  and	
  
then	
  solve	
  for	
  Q,	
  which	
  is	
  also	
  only	
  one	
  Q,	
  both	
  quan:ty	
  demanded	
  and	
  quan:ty	
  
supplied.	
  	
  A]er	
  doing	
  the	
  algebra,	
  we	
  find	
  that	
  the	
  quan:ty	
  that	
  both	
  buyers	
  and	
  
sellers	
  want	
  to	
  trade	
  is	
  10	
  units	
  of	
  the	
  good.	
  	
  By	
  plugging	
  this	
  value	
  of	
  Q	
  in	
  any	
  of	
  the	
  
original	
  equa:ons,	
  we	
  find	
  the	
  equilibrium	
  price,	
  which	
  is	
  $4/unit.	
  	
  I	
  do	
  the	
  
subs:tu:on	
  with	
  both	
  equa:ons,	
  demand	
  and	
  supply,	
  to	
  show	
  that	
  the	
  result	
  must	
  
be	
  the	
  same.	
  
…	
  
The	
  equilibrium	
  is	
  a	
  pair	
  of	
  numbers,	
  a	
  price	
  and	
  a	
  quan:ty:	
  10	
  units	
  of	
  the	
  good	
  and	
  
$4/unit.	
  
	
  
	
  




                                                                                                                                                                  14	
  
Let	
  us	
  use	
  now	
  the	
  model	
  for	
  its	
  prac:cal	
  purpose.	
  	
  We	
  need	
  it	
  to	
  predict	
  the	
  
response	
  of	
  the	
  market	
  to	
  changes	
  in	
  the	
  economic	
  environment.	
  	
  	
  
	
  
Say,	
  for	
  example,	
  that	
  we	
  want	
  to	
  know	
  the	
  effect	
  on	
  the	
  market	
  (on	
  its	
  Q*	
  and	
  P*)	
  of	
  
a	
  new	
  sales	
  tax	
  by	
  of	
  $2/unit	
  of	
  the	
  good.	
  	
  Note	
  that	
  the	
  same	
  effect	
  would	
  result	
  
from	
  any	
  other	
  change	
  in	
  the	
  economic	
  environment	
  leading	
  to	
  a	
  le]ward	
  shi]	
  of	
  the	
  
supply	
  curve	
  of	
  the	
  same	
  size.	
  
	
  
The	
  result	
  is	
  a	
  new	
  equilibrium.	
  	
  A	
  higher	
  price	
  and	
  a	
  smaller	
  quan:ty.	
  	
  I’ll	
  leave	
  up	
  to	
  
you	
  to	
  consider	
  what	
  happens	
  to	
  the	
  equilibrium	
  price	
  and	
  quan:ty	
  if	
  the	
  supply	
  
curve	
  shi]s	
  to	
  the	
  right	
  instead.	
  	
  Also,	
  what	
  happens	
  to	
  the	
  market	
  (to	
  Q*	
  and	
  P*)	
  if	
  
the	
  supply	
  curve	
  does	
  not	
  move,	
  but	
  the	
  demand	
  curve	
  shi]s	
  to	
  the	
  right	
  and	
  le]?	
  	
  
Play	
  with	
  the	
  model	
  un:l	
  you	
  feel	
  comfortable	
  enough	
  understanding	
  its	
  mechanics	
  
and	
  implica:ons.	
  




                                                                                                                                                      15	
  
Let	
  us	
  now	
  do	
  the	
  algebra	
  for	
  the	
  new	
  condi:ons	
  in	
  the	
  market.	
  	
  The	
  demand	
  
equa:on	
  stays	
  the	
  same.	
  	
  But	
  the	
  supply	
  curve	
  has	
  a	
  new	
  –	
  higher	
  –	
  intercept:	
  	
  The	
  
supply	
  equa:on	
  is	
  now	
  P	
  =	
  4	
  +	
  .2	
  Qs.	
  
	
  
Let	
  us	
  solve	
  the	
  new	
  system	
  for	
  P*	
  and	
  Q*.	
  	
  Again,	
  since	
  the	
  price	
  has	
  to	
  be	
  the	
  same	
  
for	
  both	
  buyers	
  and	
  sellers,	
  then	
  we	
  can	
  make	
  the	
  RHS	
  of	
  these	
  equa:ons	
  equal	
  and	
  
then	
  solve	
  for	
  Q,	
  which	
  is	
  also	
  only	
  one	
  Q,	
  both	
  quan:ty	
  demanded	
  and	
  quan:ty	
  
supplied.	
  	
  We	
  find	
  that	
  the	
  quan:ty	
  that	
  both	
  buyers	
  and	
  sellers	
  want	
  to	
  trade	
  is	
  8	
  
units	
  of	
  the	
  good.	
  	
  	
  
	
  
Again,	
  we	
  plug	
  this	
  value	
  of	
  Q	
  in	
  any	
  of	
  the	
  original	
  equa:ons	
  to	
  find	
  the	
  equilibrium	
  
price,	
  which	
  is	
  now	
  $5.6/unit.	
  	
  I	
  do	
  this	
  subs:tu:on	
  in	
  both	
  equa:ons,	
  demand	
  and	
  
supply,	
  to	
  show	
  again	
  that	
  the	
  result	
  is	
  the	
  same.	
  	
  The	
  new	
  equilibrium	
  is	
  8	
  units	
  of	
  
the	
  good	
  and	
  $5.6/unit.	
  
	
  
	
  




                                                                                                                                                     16	
  
17	
  
18	
  
Suppose	
  the	
  price	
  in	
  the	
  market	
  is	
  $4/unit.	
  	
  The	
  amount	
  that	
  buyers	
  will	
  buy	
  at	
  that	
  
price	
  is	
  10	
  units.	
  	
  The	
  buyers’	
  total	
  benefit	
  (so-­‐called	
  “consumer”	
  benefit)	
  is	
  the	
  area	
  
under	
  the	
  demand	
  curve	
  and	
  bound	
  by	
  the	
  quan:ty:	
  10	
  units.	
  	
  Now,	
  the	
  buyers	
  
spend	
  in	
  the	
  good:	
  P	
  Q	
  =	
  ($4/unit)	
  (10	
  units)	
  =	
  $40.	
  	
  They	
  receive	
  the	
  10	
  units	
  of	
  the	
  
good	
  that	
  yields	
  for	
  them	
  the	
  total	
  benefit.	
  	
  However,	
  a	
  por:on	
  of	
  the	
  total	
  benefit	
  –	
  
the	
  rectangle	
  represen:ng	
  their	
  expenditure	
  –	
  is	
  not	
  free.	
  	
  They	
  pay	
  for	
  that.	
  	
  S:ll,	
  
there	
  is	
  the	
  triangle	
  above	
  the	
  expenditure	
  rectangle	
  for	
  which	
  buyers	
  pay	
  nothing.	
  	
  It	
  
is	
  their	
  net	
  benefit	
  or	
  “consumer	
  surplus.”	
  	
  It	
  is	
  the	
  welfare	
  that	
  buyers	
  receive	
  for	
  
free	
  from	
  the	
  amount	
  of	
  the	
  good	
  they	
  buy	
  from	
  the	
  sellers.	
  	
  They	
  receive	
  this	
  net	
  
benefit	
  or	
  “consumer	
  surplus”	
  because	
  the	
  market	
  exists	
  –	
  because	
  there	
  is	
  another	
  
side	
  to	
  the	
  market,	
  because	
  there	
  are	
  sellers	
  willing	
  to	
  cooperate	
  or	
  trade	
  with	
  them.	
  	
  
This	
  is	
  the	
  source	
  of	
  the	
  consumer	
  surplus.	
  
	
  
The	
  consumer	
  surplus	
  is	
  represented	
  by	
  the	
  area	
  of	
  that	
  triangle.	
  	
  To	
  calculate	
  the	
  
area,	
  we	
  use	
  the	
  formula	
  (b	
  h)/2.	
  	
  In	
  this	
  case,	
  the	
  base	
  is	
  10	
  units	
  and	
  the	
  height	
  is	
  
the	
  intercept	
  of	
  the	
  demand	
  curve	
  minus	
  the	
  price	
  in	
  the	
  market,	
  which	
  is	
  $4/unit.	
  	
  
Therefore,	
  it	
  is	
  12-­‐4	
  =	
  8,	
  mul:plied	
  by	
  10,	
  that	
  is	
  80,	
  and	
  80	
  divided	
  by	
  2	
  is	
  40.	
  	
  Note	
  
that	
  the	
  units	
  are	
  just	
  dollars:	
  $40.	
  	
  The	
  values	
  on	
  the	
  ver:cal	
  axis	
  are	
  prices:	
  $/unit.	
  	
  
So	
  $12/unit	
  minus	
  $4/unit	
  =	
  $8/unit.	
  	
  Now	
  when	
  you	
  mul:ply	
  $/unit	
  :mes	
  units,	
  the	
  
units	
  cancel	
  out,	
  and	
  you	
  obtain	
  $,	
  just	
  plain	
  dollars.	
  
	
  




                                                                                                                                                             19	
  
20	
  
Let	
  us	
  now	
  calculate	
  the	
  producer	
  surplus.	
  
	
  
Again,	
  if	
  the	
  price	
  in	
  the	
  market	
  is	
  $4/unit.	
  	
  The	
  amount	
  that	
  sellers	
  will	
  sell	
  at	
  that	
  
price	
  is	
  10	
  units.	
  Remember	
  that	
  the	
  height	
  of	
  the	
  supply	
  curve	
  indicates	
  the	
  lowest	
  
price	
  that	
  sellers	
  ask	
  for	
  one	
  unit	
  of	
  the	
  good,	
  and	
  that	
  is	
  precisely	
  the	
  cost	
  of	
  the	
  
good	
  for	
  them.	
  	
  The	
  sellers’	
  total	
  receipts	
  or	
  revenues	
  are	
  P	
  Q	
  =	
  (4)	
  (10)	
  =	
  $40.	
  	
  That	
  is	
  
represented	
  by	
  this	
  rectangle.	
  	
  The	
  area	
  below	
  the	
  supply	
  curve	
  and	
  bound	
  by	
  the	
  
quan:ty:	
  10	
  units	
  is	
  the	
  cost	
  for	
  the	
  producers.	
  Note	
  that	
  the	
  sellers’	
  revenues	
  P	
  Q,	
  
$40,	
  are	
  more	
  than	
  the	
  sellers’	
  cost.	
  	
  The	
  difference	
  of	
  R	
  –	
  C	
  =	
  profit.	
  	
  The	
  profit	
  is	
  
also	
  called	
  the	
  “producer	
  surplus.”	
  
	
  
The	
  consumer	
  surplus	
  is	
  represented	
  by	
  the	
  area	
  of	
  this	
  triangle.	
  	
  Again,	
  the	
  area	
  is	
  (b	
  
h)/2.	
  	
  In	
  this	
  case,	
  the	
  base	
  is	
  10	
  units	
  and	
  the	
  height	
  is	
  the	
  market	
  price,	
  $4/unit,	
  
minus	
  the	
  intercept	
  of	
  the	
  supply	
  curve,	
  $2/unit.	
  	
  The	
  height	
  is	
  then	
  4-­‐2	
  =	
  $2/unit.	
  	
  
Therefore,	
  the	
  producer	
  surplus	
  is	
  (10)	
  (2)	
  =	
  20,	
  divided	
  by	
  2:	
  $10.	
  	
  
	
  
So,	
  the	
  net	
  welfare	
  benefit	
  of	
  the	
  sellers,	
  their	
  profit	
  or	
  producer	
  surplus,	
  is	
  a	
  
measure	
  of	
  the	
  welfare	
  of	
  sellers	
  in	
  the	
  market	
  –	
  something	
  they	
  receive	
  for	
  free,	
  
because	
  the	
  market	
  exists.	
  	
  It	
  is	
  calculated	
  in	
  dollars.	
  	
  It’s	
  $10.	
  




                                                                                                                                                             21	
  
The	
  total	
  surplus	
  or	
  the	
  net	
  welfare	
  benefit	
  that	
  the	
  buyers	
  and	
  sellers	
  receive	
  
altogether	
  is	
  the	
  sum	
  of	
  the	
  consumer	
  and	
  the	
  producer	
  surpluses.	
  




                                                                                                                             22	
  
In	
  other	
  words,	
  the	
  total	
  surplus	
  is	
  equal	
  to	
  $40	
  +	
  $10	
  =	
  $50.	
  
	
  
To	
  repeat:	
  This	
  is	
  a	
  measure	
  of	
  the	
  net	
  welfare	
  benefits	
  that	
  both	
  buyers	
  and	
  sellers	
  
together	
  receive	
  as	
  a	
  result	
  of	
  the	
  existence	
  of	
  the	
  market,	
  which	
  is	
  to	
  say,	
  as	
  a	
  result	
  
of	
  their	
  coopera:ng	
  with	
  each	
  other.	
  	
  It’s	
  the	
  fruits	
  of	
  their	
  coopera:on,	
  which	
  –	
  in	
  
this	
  par:cular	
  case	
  –	
  takes	
  the	
  form	
  of	
  trade.	
  
	
  
And	
  to	
  keep	
  the	
  :me	
  of	
  this	
  videos	
  short,	
  there’s	
  no	
  summary.	
  	
  You	
  can	
  go	
  back	
  and	
  
replay	
  the	
  parts	
  that	
  you	
  may	
  need	
  to	
  study	
  more	
  carefully.	
  
	
  
I	
  hope	
  this	
  was	
  helpful	
  to	
  you.	
  	
  I’ll	
  see	
  you	
  in	
  class.	
  




                                                                                                                                                   23	
  

Mais conteúdo relacionado

Mais de Julio Huato

Hecksher-Ohlin model
Hecksher-Ohlin modelHecksher-Ohlin model
Hecksher-Ohlin modelJulio Huato
 
Int econ bases_trade
Int econ bases_tradeInt econ bases_trade
Int econ bases_tradeJulio Huato
 
A two-good economy
A two-good economyA two-good economy
A two-good economyJulio Huato
 
Applied Statistics - Parametric Distributions
Applied Statistics - Parametric DistributionsApplied Statistics - Parametric Distributions
Applied Statistics - Parametric DistributionsJulio Huato
 
Two-good output choice
Two-good output choiceTwo-good output choice
Two-good output choiceJulio Huato
 
Statistics - Probability theory 1
Statistics - Probability theory 1Statistics - Probability theory 1
Statistics - Probability theory 1Julio Huato
 
Intecon micro review 1
Intecon micro review 1Intecon micro review 1
Intecon micro review 1Julio Huato
 
Applied Statistics - Introduction
Applied Statistics - IntroductionApplied Statistics - Introduction
Applied Statistics - IntroductionJulio Huato
 
Summation Operator
Summation OperatorSummation Operator
Summation OperatorJulio Huato
 
Inputs output costs
Inputs output costsInputs output costs
Inputs output costsJulio Huato
 
Slides money banking risk reward capm
Slides money banking risk reward capmSlides money banking risk reward capm
Slides money banking risk reward capmJulio Huato
 
Slides money banking time value
Slides money banking time valueSlides money banking time value
Slides money banking time valueJulio Huato
 

Mais de Julio Huato (20)

Int Econ BoP
Int Econ BoPInt Econ BoP
Int Econ BoP
 
Hecksher-Ohlin model
Hecksher-Ohlin modelHecksher-Ohlin model
Hecksher-Ohlin model
 
Ricardian model
Ricardian modelRicardian model
Ricardian model
 
Int econ bases_trade
Int econ bases_tradeInt econ bases_trade
Int econ bases_trade
 
Fin sys
Fin sysFin sys
Fin sys
 
A two-good economy
A two-good economyA two-good economy
A two-good economy
 
Applied Statistics - Parametric Distributions
Applied Statistics - Parametric DistributionsApplied Statistics - Parametric Distributions
Applied Statistics - Parametric Distributions
 
Two-good output choice
Two-good output choiceTwo-good output choice
Two-good output choice
 
Statistics - Probability theory 1
Statistics - Probability theory 1Statistics - Probability theory 1
Statistics - Probability theory 1
 
Intecon micro review 1
Intecon micro review 1Intecon micro review 1
Intecon micro review 1
 
Applied Statistics - Introduction
Applied Statistics - IntroductionApplied Statistics - Introduction
Applied Statistics - Introduction
 
Summation Operator
Summation OperatorSummation Operator
Summation Operator
 
Inputs output costs
Inputs output costsInputs output costs
Inputs output costs
 
Risk
RiskRisk
Risk
 
Elasticity
ElasticityElasticity
Elasticity
 
Slides money banking risk reward capm
Slides money banking risk reward capmSlides money banking risk reward capm
Slides money banking risk reward capm
 
Slides money banking time value
Slides money banking time valueSlides money banking time value
Slides money banking time value
 
Market model
Market modelMarket model
Market model
 
Macro review
Macro reviewMacro review
Macro review
 
Micro review 2
Micro review 2Micro review 2
Micro review 2
 

Último

Grade Three -ELLNA-REVIEWER-ENGLISH.pptx
Grade Three -ELLNA-REVIEWER-ENGLISH.pptxGrade Three -ELLNA-REVIEWER-ENGLISH.pptx
Grade Three -ELLNA-REVIEWER-ENGLISH.pptxkarenfajardo43
 
DIFFERENT BASKETRY IN THE PHILIPPINES PPT.pptx
DIFFERENT BASKETRY IN THE PHILIPPINES PPT.pptxDIFFERENT BASKETRY IN THE PHILIPPINES PPT.pptx
DIFFERENT BASKETRY IN THE PHILIPPINES PPT.pptxMichelleTuguinay1
 
ClimART Action | eTwinning Project
ClimART Action    |    eTwinning ProjectClimART Action    |    eTwinning Project
ClimART Action | eTwinning Projectjordimapav
 
INTRODUCTION TO CATHOLIC CHRISTOLOGY.pptx
INTRODUCTION TO CATHOLIC CHRISTOLOGY.pptxINTRODUCTION TO CATHOLIC CHRISTOLOGY.pptx
INTRODUCTION TO CATHOLIC CHRISTOLOGY.pptxHumphrey A Beña
 
Grade 9 Quarter 4 Dll Grade 9 Quarter 4 DLL.pdf
Grade 9 Quarter 4 Dll Grade 9 Quarter 4 DLL.pdfGrade 9 Quarter 4 Dll Grade 9 Quarter 4 DLL.pdf
Grade 9 Quarter 4 Dll Grade 9 Quarter 4 DLL.pdfJemuel Francisco
 
Expanded definition: technical and operational
Expanded definition: technical and operationalExpanded definition: technical and operational
Expanded definition: technical and operationalssuser3e220a
 
Q-Factor General Quiz-7th April 2024, Quiz Club NITW
Q-Factor General Quiz-7th April 2024, Quiz Club NITWQ-Factor General Quiz-7th April 2024, Quiz Club NITW
Q-Factor General Quiz-7th April 2024, Quiz Club NITWQuiz Club NITW
 
ESP 4-EDITED.pdfmmcncncncmcmmnmnmncnmncmnnjvnnv
ESP 4-EDITED.pdfmmcncncncmcmmnmnmncnmncmnnjvnnvESP 4-EDITED.pdfmmcncncncmcmmnmnmncnmncmnnjvnnv
ESP 4-EDITED.pdfmmcncncncmcmmnmnmncnmncmnnjvnnvRicaMaeCastro1
 
Congestive Cardiac Failure..presentation
Congestive Cardiac Failure..presentationCongestive Cardiac Failure..presentation
Congestive Cardiac Failure..presentationdeepaannamalai16
 
Q-Factor HISPOL Quiz-6th April 2024, Quiz Club NITW
Q-Factor HISPOL Quiz-6th April 2024, Quiz Club NITWQ-Factor HISPOL Quiz-6th April 2024, Quiz Club NITW
Q-Factor HISPOL Quiz-6th April 2024, Quiz Club NITWQuiz Club NITW
 
Mental Health Awareness - a toolkit for supporting young minds
Mental Health Awareness - a toolkit for supporting young mindsMental Health Awareness - a toolkit for supporting young minds
Mental Health Awareness - a toolkit for supporting young mindsPooky Knightsmith
 
4.16.24 21st Century Movements for Black Lives.pptx
4.16.24 21st Century Movements for Black Lives.pptx4.16.24 21st Century Movements for Black Lives.pptx
4.16.24 21st Century Movements for Black Lives.pptxmary850239
 
Using Grammatical Signals Suitable to Patterns of Idea Development
Using Grammatical Signals Suitable to Patterns of Idea DevelopmentUsing Grammatical Signals Suitable to Patterns of Idea Development
Using Grammatical Signals Suitable to Patterns of Idea Developmentchesterberbo7
 
31 ĐỀ THI THỬ VÀO LỚP 10 - TIẾNG ANH - FORM MỚI 2025 - 40 CÂU HỎI - BÙI VĂN V...
31 ĐỀ THI THỬ VÀO LỚP 10 - TIẾNG ANH - FORM MỚI 2025 - 40 CÂU HỎI - BÙI VĂN V...31 ĐỀ THI THỬ VÀO LỚP 10 - TIẾNG ANH - FORM MỚI 2025 - 40 CÂU HỎI - BÙI VĂN V...
31 ĐỀ THI THỬ VÀO LỚP 10 - TIẾNG ANH - FORM MỚI 2025 - 40 CÂU HỎI - BÙI VĂN V...Nguyen Thanh Tu Collection
 
Decoding the Tweet _ Practical Criticism in the Age of Hashtag.pptx
Decoding the Tweet _ Practical Criticism in the Age of Hashtag.pptxDecoding the Tweet _ Practical Criticism in the Age of Hashtag.pptx
Decoding the Tweet _ Practical Criticism in the Age of Hashtag.pptxDhatriParmar
 
Team Lead Succeed – Helping you and your team achieve high-performance teamwo...
Team Lead Succeed – Helping you and your team achieve high-performance teamwo...Team Lead Succeed – Helping you and your team achieve high-performance teamwo...
Team Lead Succeed – Helping you and your team achieve high-performance teamwo...Association for Project Management
 

Último (20)

Grade Three -ELLNA-REVIEWER-ENGLISH.pptx
Grade Three -ELLNA-REVIEWER-ENGLISH.pptxGrade Three -ELLNA-REVIEWER-ENGLISH.pptx
Grade Three -ELLNA-REVIEWER-ENGLISH.pptx
 
DIFFERENT BASKETRY IN THE PHILIPPINES PPT.pptx
DIFFERENT BASKETRY IN THE PHILIPPINES PPT.pptxDIFFERENT BASKETRY IN THE PHILIPPINES PPT.pptx
DIFFERENT BASKETRY IN THE PHILIPPINES PPT.pptx
 
ClimART Action | eTwinning Project
ClimART Action    |    eTwinning ProjectClimART Action    |    eTwinning Project
ClimART Action | eTwinning Project
 
INTRODUCTION TO CATHOLIC CHRISTOLOGY.pptx
INTRODUCTION TO CATHOLIC CHRISTOLOGY.pptxINTRODUCTION TO CATHOLIC CHRISTOLOGY.pptx
INTRODUCTION TO CATHOLIC CHRISTOLOGY.pptx
 
prashanth updated resume 2024 for Teaching Profession
prashanth updated resume 2024 for Teaching Professionprashanth updated resume 2024 for Teaching Profession
prashanth updated resume 2024 for Teaching Profession
 
Grade 9 Quarter 4 Dll Grade 9 Quarter 4 DLL.pdf
Grade 9 Quarter 4 Dll Grade 9 Quarter 4 DLL.pdfGrade 9 Quarter 4 Dll Grade 9 Quarter 4 DLL.pdf
Grade 9 Quarter 4 Dll Grade 9 Quarter 4 DLL.pdf
 
Expanded definition: technical and operational
Expanded definition: technical and operationalExpanded definition: technical and operational
Expanded definition: technical and operational
 
Q-Factor General Quiz-7th April 2024, Quiz Club NITW
Q-Factor General Quiz-7th April 2024, Quiz Club NITWQ-Factor General Quiz-7th April 2024, Quiz Club NITW
Q-Factor General Quiz-7th April 2024, Quiz Club NITW
 
ESP 4-EDITED.pdfmmcncncncmcmmnmnmncnmncmnnjvnnv
ESP 4-EDITED.pdfmmcncncncmcmmnmnmncnmncmnnjvnnvESP 4-EDITED.pdfmmcncncncmcmmnmnmncnmncmnnjvnnv
ESP 4-EDITED.pdfmmcncncncmcmmnmnmncnmncmnnjvnnv
 
INCLUSIVE EDUCATION PRACTICES FOR TEACHERS AND TRAINERS.pptx
INCLUSIVE EDUCATION PRACTICES FOR TEACHERS AND TRAINERS.pptxINCLUSIVE EDUCATION PRACTICES FOR TEACHERS AND TRAINERS.pptx
INCLUSIVE EDUCATION PRACTICES FOR TEACHERS AND TRAINERS.pptx
 
Congestive Cardiac Failure..presentation
Congestive Cardiac Failure..presentationCongestive Cardiac Failure..presentation
Congestive Cardiac Failure..presentation
 
Q-Factor HISPOL Quiz-6th April 2024, Quiz Club NITW
Q-Factor HISPOL Quiz-6th April 2024, Quiz Club NITWQ-Factor HISPOL Quiz-6th April 2024, Quiz Club NITW
Q-Factor HISPOL Quiz-6th April 2024, Quiz Club NITW
 
Mental Health Awareness - a toolkit for supporting young minds
Mental Health Awareness - a toolkit for supporting young mindsMental Health Awareness - a toolkit for supporting young minds
Mental Health Awareness - a toolkit for supporting young minds
 
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: Large Language Models"
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: Large Language Models"Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: Large Language Models"
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: Large Language Models"
 
4.16.24 21st Century Movements for Black Lives.pptx
4.16.24 21st Century Movements for Black Lives.pptx4.16.24 21st Century Movements for Black Lives.pptx
4.16.24 21st Century Movements for Black Lives.pptx
 
Using Grammatical Signals Suitable to Patterns of Idea Development
Using Grammatical Signals Suitable to Patterns of Idea DevelopmentUsing Grammatical Signals Suitable to Patterns of Idea Development
Using Grammatical Signals Suitable to Patterns of Idea Development
 
Faculty Profile prashantha K EEE dept Sri Sairam college of Engineering
Faculty Profile prashantha K EEE dept Sri Sairam college of EngineeringFaculty Profile prashantha K EEE dept Sri Sairam college of Engineering
Faculty Profile prashantha K EEE dept Sri Sairam college of Engineering
 
31 ĐỀ THI THỬ VÀO LỚP 10 - TIẾNG ANH - FORM MỚI 2025 - 40 CÂU HỎI - BÙI VĂN V...
31 ĐỀ THI THỬ VÀO LỚP 10 - TIẾNG ANH - FORM MỚI 2025 - 40 CÂU HỎI - BÙI VĂN V...31 ĐỀ THI THỬ VÀO LỚP 10 - TIẾNG ANH - FORM MỚI 2025 - 40 CÂU HỎI - BÙI VĂN V...
31 ĐỀ THI THỬ VÀO LỚP 10 - TIẾNG ANH - FORM MỚI 2025 - 40 CÂU HỎI - BÙI VĂN V...
 
Decoding the Tweet _ Practical Criticism in the Age of Hashtag.pptx
Decoding the Tweet _ Practical Criticism in the Age of Hashtag.pptxDecoding the Tweet _ Practical Criticism in the Age of Hashtag.pptx
Decoding the Tweet _ Practical Criticism in the Age of Hashtag.pptx
 
Team Lead Succeed – Helping you and your team achieve high-performance teamwo...
Team Lead Succeed – Helping you and your team achieve high-performance teamwo...Team Lead Succeed – Helping you and your team achieve high-performance teamwo...
Team Lead Succeed – Helping you and your team achieve high-performance teamwo...
 

Intecon micro review 1

  • 1. This  video  clip  reviews  the  microeconomic  concepts  that  we’ll  be  using  in  our  course.   -­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐  Mee:ng  Notes  (1/22/12  08:53)  -­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐   In  our  interna:onal  economics  course.   1  
  • 2. The  review  includes  two  items:  (1)  the  mechanics  of  the  simple  model  of  a   compe::ve  market  that  economists  use  and  (2)  the  underpinnings  of  the   conven:onal  choice  theory  –  both  collec:ve  and  individual.       2  
  • 3. First  off,  what  is  a  market?         For  our  purposes  here,  we’ll  view  a  market  as  a  bunch  of  people  trading  a  good  on  a   voluntary  basis.    The  good  defines  the  market.    If  the  good  is  oranges,  then  it  is  a   market  for  oranges.         Markets  are  social  structures  –  people  rela:ng  to  one  another  in  certain  ways  (in  this   case,  acknowledging  and  respec:ng  their  mutual  property  and  coopera:ng  with  one   another  via  trade).    For  more  on  this,  see  my  slides  on  Coopera:on  &  Social   Structures.     At  this  point,  we  make  the  assump:on  that  this  market  is  compe::ve.    By  this  we   mean,  first,  that  the  good  is  homogeneous.    There  are  no  differences  in  the  quality  or   characteris:cs  of  the  good.    Say  it  is  oranges.    They  are  generic  oranges.    For  a  buyer,   it  doesn’t  maVer  who  supplies  the  oranges,  because  they  all  look  and  taste  and  smell   the  same.    And  second,  to  say  that  the  market  is  compe::ve  is  to  say  that  there  are   many  buyers  and  many  sellers,  so  no  par:cular  buyer  or  seller  has  “market  power”  –   i.e.  the  ability  to  manipulate  the  price  individually.    And  since  there  are  many  and  the   good  is  the  same,  the  sellers  cannot  differen:ate  the  good  or  form  coali:ons.     Neither  can  the  buyers.    Basically,  it’s  just  a  bunch  of  individual  buyers  and  sellers   trying  to  do  the  best  they  can  for  each  of  them  individually  without  regard  for  the     3  
  • 4. We  split  the  people  into  two  groups  –  one  group,  we  call  the  buyers.    These  people   have  money  and  want  the  good.    The  second  group  is  the  sellers.    These  people  have   the  good,  but  they  want  the  money.    The  two  groups  meet  and  make  the  market  by   nego:a:ng  prices  at  which  they  are  willing  to  trade.    There  will  be  a  single  price  in   this  market,  at  which  all  buyers  will  buy  the  good  and  all  sellers  will  sell  the  good.     Once  the  two  groups  agree  on  a  price  such  that  the  buyers  want  to  buy  the  same   amount  of  the  good  that  the  sellers  wish  to  sell  –  and  we  call  that  the  “market   equilibrium”  –  the  deal  is  made,  they  shake  hands,  sellers  hand  the  good  to  the   buyers,  buyers  pay  the  sellers  the  money,  and  each  group  goes  home  happier  or  at   least  not  less  happy  than  they  were  before.    Remember:  it  is  a  voluntary  transac:on.     If  people  felt  that  trading  made  them  less  happy,  then  why  would  they  do  it   voluntarily?     We  construct  the  model  in  the  following  way:  First,  we  study  the  behavior  of  buyers.     We  call  that  the  demand  side.    Second,  we  study  the  behavior  of  the  sellers.    We  call   that  the  supply  side.    Third,  we  put  the  two  together.    We  call  that  equilibrium.     Fourth,  we  study  how  equilibrium  is  aVained.    Fi]h,  we  shock  the  model  by  making   some  or  other  factor  (other  than  price)  affect  the  behavior  of  buyers  or  sellers  or   both,  and  see  what  the  model  predicts.    This  is  the  way  in  which  we  test  the  model.     If  the  predic:ons  of  the  model  match  what  we  observe  in  reality,  then  –  and  to  that   extent  –  we  deem  the  model  as  reliable  and  use  it  in  our  prac:cal  applica:ons.       4  
  • 5. Demand.     The  ques:on  we  pose  here  is:  What  makes  buyers  buy  more  (or  less)  of  a  good?     There  are  many  factors.    Let  me  limit  my  list  to  a  few  of  these  factors:       Price  is  the  first  one.    And  in  the  graphic  model  that  we  use,  this  is  the  variable  that  is   explicitly  included  in  the  analysis.    Economists  say  that  this  variable,  price,  and  the   quan:ty  traded  (demanded  and  supplied)  are  the  *endogenous*  variables.    Other   variables,  which  are  not  explicitly  visible  in  the  analysis,  are  called  *exogenous*.    It   doesn’t  mean  that  we  don’t  care  about  them.    We  have  ways  to  reflect  the  impact  of   changes  on  those  variables  on  our  market  model  –  on  price  and  quan:ty.    But  our   liVle  model  cannot  explain  *why*  they  change.    We  are  just  going  to  assume,   whenever  we  may  deem  that  convenient,  that  these  variables  change  and  then   register  the  effect  of  those  changes  on  price  and  quan:ty.     Price  maVers  here,  because  –  and  this  seems  like  a  reasonable  assump:on  to  make,   since  it  appears  to  match  what  we  observe  in  the  world  –  if  the  price  is  higher,  buyers   will  tend  to  buy  less  of  the  good.    If,  on  the  other  hand,  the  price  is  lower,  buyers  will   tend  to  buy  more.    So,  there’s  a  nega:ve  or  inverse  rela:onship  between  price  and   quan:ty  demanded  –  the  quan:ty  that  buyers  wish  to  buy  given  all  other  things.     5  
  • 6. Here’s  the  graph  of  the  demand  rela:onship.           This  graph  (the  curve  or  line)  shows  directly  the  rela:onship  between  the  quan:ty   demanded  for  the  good  and  the  price  of  the  good.    It  is  a  nega:ve  rela:onship.    That   is  why  the  slope  of  the  line  is  nega:ve.    The  line  is  downward  sloping.    Now,  for   simplicity,  I’m  drawing  it  as  a  straight  line.    Real  demand  lines,  if  we  are  able  to   es:mate  them  (and  there  are  difficul:es  to  es:mate  them  empirically),  don’t  need  to   be  straight  lines.    This  is  a  simplifica:on,  but  it  is  a  simplifica:on  that  helps  us  clarify   things  nicely.     Note  that  in  this  graph,  we  can  only  show  two  variables  explicitly  or  directly.    As  I   said,  the  two  variables  we  care  most  about  are  the  price  and  the  quan:ty  traded.    So   the  graph  only  shows  the  link  between  price  and  quan:ty  explicitly.      When  we   consider  the  change  in  the  price  of  the  good  and  then  the  reac:on  of  buyers,  then  we   say  that  we  are  “moving  along”  the  demand  line  or  demand  curve.         Let  me  note  that  we  are  drawing  the  demand  curve  as  a  straight  line  for  convenience   only.    There  is  no  reason  why  an  actual  demand  curve  would  be  linear.     6  
  • 7. When  other  factors  (not  explicitly  indicated  -­‐-­‐  the  factors  that  we  listed  before:   income,  tastes,  other  prices,  expecta:ons)…  when  those  factors  change,  that  has  an   effect  on  the  whole  demand  line.      The  demand  line  shi]s.    For  example,  suppose  that   this  is  the  market  for  oranges  and  the  price  of  apples  increases.    Then,  as  a  result,  the   en:re  demand  line  for  oranges  may  shi]  to  the  right  –  indica:ng  that  for  each  given   price,  buyers  are  willing  to  buy  more  oranges  due  to  the  higher  price  of  apples.    This   is  called  a  rightward  *shi]*  of  the  demand  line.    It  is  easy  to  see  that  the  effect  of   changes  in  the  other  variables  listed  (variables  other  than  price  and  the  quan:ty   demanded)  can  be  shown  in  this  graph  as  a  shi]  of  the  demand  line.     Now,  just  by  looking  at  the  shi]  in  the  diagram,  we  may  not  be  able  to  know  what   cause  that  shi].    So,  we’ll  need  to  add  separate  informa:on  to  our  diagram  so  that   we  know  why  the  graph,  the  demand  line  shi]ed.   7  
  • 8. Let  us  now  consider  …  supply.    This  is  the  descrip:on  of  how  the  sellers  (the  other   side  of  the  market)  behave.     The  ques:on  here  is:  What  makes  sellers  sell  more  (or  less)  of  a  good?    There  are  also   many  factors.    These  are  a  few  important  ones:       Price  is,  again,  the  first  one.    The  higher  the  price,  the  more  of  the  good  the  sellers   would  want  to  sell,  other  things  equal.     Suppose  that  the  producers  and,  more  generally,  the  sellers  of  the  good  are  business   people.    They  are  offering  the  good  for  sale,  because  they  want  to  make  a  profit.  The   profit  they  obtain  per  unit  of  the  good  is  the  difference  between  the  price  of  the   good  and  the  cost  of  the  good  for  them.    Let  us  define  here  the  cost  of  the  good  as   the  minimum  price  at  which  the  sellers  are  willing  to  sell  the  good.    Clearly,  if  the  cost   of  the  good  is  given,  the  higher  the  price,  the  higher  their  profit.    On  the  other  hand,   if  the  price  of  the  good  is  given,  then  the  lower  the  cost  of  the  good,  the  higher  the   profit.     Given  the  price  of  the  good,  its  cost  is  going  to  be  their  main  considera:on  when   deciding  how  much  of  the  good  to  sell.    What  is  the  cost:  Well,  if  they  are  the   producers,  they  need  to  assemble  the  inputs  required  to  produce  the  good  and  pay     8  
  • 9. Here’s  the  graph  of  the  supply  rela:onship.           This  graph  (the  curve  or  line)  shows  directly  the  rela:onship  between  the  quan:ty   supplied  of  the  good  and  the  price  of  the  good.    It  is  a  posi:ve  rela:onship.  The   supply  curve  or  line  is  upward  sloping.    For  simplicity,  I  draw  it  as  a  straight  line.    Real   supply  lines,  also  hard  to  es:mate  empirically,  don’t  need  to  be  straight  lines.    But  we   are  simplifying  maVers.     You  will  note  that  the  supply  curve  here  is  also  a  straight  line,  just  like  the  demand   curve  was  a  straight  line.    Again,  this  is  for  convenience  only.    There  is  no  reason  why   an  actual  demand  or  supply  curves  would  be  linear.       Now,  again,  if  we  are  studying  the  change  in  the  price  of  the  good  and  how  sellers   react  to  it,  we  are  “moving  along”  the  supply  curve.       9  
  • 10. When  the  other  factors  change,  the  supply  curve  shi]s  en:rely.    Suppose  that  this  is   the  market  for  oranges  and  the  price  of  labor  decreases  (say,  there  is  high   unemployment  in  the  area  and  workers  have  to  accept  lower  wages).    Then,  as  a   result,  the  en:re  supply  curve  to  the  right  –  indica:ng  that  for  each  given  price,   sellers  are  willing  to  sell  more  oranges  due  to  the  lower  cost  of  labor.    This  is  called  a   rightward  *shi]*  of  the  supply  curve.         And  when  any  of  the  other  factors  may  change,  we  can  do  something  similar  to   register  that  change  and  its  effect  on  the  market  in  our  diagram.   10  
  • 11. We  are  now  ready  to  put  the  demand  and  the  supply  sides  together.    In  the  diagram,   we  show  now  the  demand  and  the  supply  curves.    Demand  is  downward  sloping.     Supply  is  upward  sloping.    As  a  result,  they  cross  at  a  point.    Let  us  examine  the  point   where  they  cross.     The  demand  curve  shows  the  different  quan::es  of  the  good  that  buyers  wish  to  buy   at  different  prices  (given  the  economic  environment).    The  supply  curve  shows  the   different  quan::es  of  the  good  that  sellers  wish  to  sell  at  different  prices  (again,   given  the  economic  environment).    The  point  where  the  two  curves  cross  is  a  price   and  a  quan:ty  –  the  price  at  which  the  quan:ty  demand  and  the  quan:ty  supplied   are  equal.     At  this  price,  buyers  and  sellers  agree  on  the  quan:ty  they  wish  to  trade.    We  call  it   equilibrium,  because  if  nothing  changes  in  the  economic  environment,  then  there  is   no  reason  why  buyers  or  sellers  may  want  to  be  somewhere  else  rather  than  at  that   point.     Consider  the  case  where  the  price  is  higher  than  the  equilibrium  price  –  say  about   here.    Note  then  that  the  quan:ty  that  buyers  want  to  buy  falls  short  of  the  quan:ty   that  sellers  want  to  sell.    As  a  consequence,  there  is  no  deal.    There  is  a  gap  between   the  quan:ty  demanded  and  the  quan:ty  supplied.    Economists  call  that  gap  a  glut.    It     11  
  • 12. Let  us  now  do  the  algebra.     The  demand  equa:on  is  this  one:  P  =  12  -­‐  .8  Qd     where  12  is  the  ver:cal  intercept  and  -­‐0.8  is  the  slope.     The  intercept  or  any  price  above  it  would  discourage  buyers  from  buying  the  good.     No  buyer  would  pay  that  much  for  the  good.  The  slope  (.8)  indicates  the  drop  in  the   price  that  would  make  buyers  buy  one  extra  unit  of  the  good.     Note  that  the  ver:cal  axis  shows  you  how  much  the  buyers  value  one  unit  of  the   good.    It  indicates  how  much  they  benefit  from  it,  since  they  would  only  pay  the   price  for  it  if  they  felt  that  the  benefit  received  compensates  them  properly.           12  
  • 13. And  here  is  the  supply  equa:on:  P  =  2  +  .2  Qs,  where  2  is  the  ver:cal  intercept  and   0.25  is  the  slope.     At  the  intercept  or  any  price  below  it,  no  seller  would  sell  any  of  the  good.    The  slope   indicates  the  increase  in  the  price  that  would  lead  sellers  to  sell  one  extra  unit  of  the   good.     It  is  important  to  note  here  that  the  ver:cal  axis  also  shows  how  much  the  sellers   value  the  good.    It  indicates  how  much  the  good  costs  the  sellers,  since  they  would   only  sell  it  if  they  feel  compensated  for  such  cost.     13  
  • 14. We  have  a  system  of  two  linear  equa:ons.    The  demand  has  to  sa:sfy  the  rule  P  =  12   -­‐  .8  Qd  and  the  supply  the  rule  that  P  =  2  +  .2  Qs.    In  equilibrium,  the  price  that  buyers   pay  is  the  same  price  that  the  sellers  receive.    And  the  quan:ty  that  the  buyers  want   to  buy  is  the  quan:ty  that  the  sellers  want  to  sell.    In  other  words,  the  equilibrium   price  and  quan:ty  are  the  values  of  P  and  Q  that  solve  the  two  equa:ons   simultaneously.     Let  us  solve  the  system  algebraically  now.    Since  the  price  has  to  be  the  same  for   both  buyers  and  sellers,  then  we  can  make  the  RHS  of  these  equa:ons  equal  and   then  solve  for  Q,  which  is  also  only  one  Q,  both  quan:ty  demanded  and  quan:ty   supplied.    A]er  doing  the  algebra,  we  find  that  the  quan:ty  that  both  buyers  and   sellers  want  to  trade  is  10  units  of  the  good.    By  plugging  this  value  of  Q  in  any  of  the   original  equa:ons,  we  find  the  equilibrium  price,  which  is  $4/unit.    I  do  the   subs:tu:on  with  both  equa:ons,  demand  and  supply,  to  show  that  the  result  must   be  the  same.   …   The  equilibrium  is  a  pair  of  numbers,  a  price  and  a  quan:ty:  10  units  of  the  good  and   $4/unit.       14  
  • 15. Let  us  use  now  the  model  for  its  prac:cal  purpose.    We  need  it  to  predict  the   response  of  the  market  to  changes  in  the  economic  environment.         Say,  for  example,  that  we  want  to  know  the  effect  on  the  market  (on  its  Q*  and  P*)  of   a  new  sales  tax  by  of  $2/unit  of  the  good.    Note  that  the  same  effect  would  result   from  any  other  change  in  the  economic  environment  leading  to  a  le]ward  shi]  of  the   supply  curve  of  the  same  size.     The  result  is  a  new  equilibrium.    A  higher  price  and  a  smaller  quan:ty.    I’ll  leave  up  to   you  to  consider  what  happens  to  the  equilibrium  price  and  quan:ty  if  the  supply   curve  shi]s  to  the  right  instead.    Also,  what  happens  to  the  market  (to  Q*  and  P*)  if   the  supply  curve  does  not  move,  but  the  demand  curve  shi]s  to  the  right  and  le]?     Play  with  the  model  un:l  you  feel  comfortable  enough  understanding  its  mechanics   and  implica:ons.   15  
  • 16. Let  us  now  do  the  algebra  for  the  new  condi:ons  in  the  market.    The  demand   equa:on  stays  the  same.    But  the  supply  curve  has  a  new  –  higher  –  intercept:    The   supply  equa:on  is  now  P  =  4  +  .2  Qs.     Let  us  solve  the  new  system  for  P*  and  Q*.    Again,  since  the  price  has  to  be  the  same   for  both  buyers  and  sellers,  then  we  can  make  the  RHS  of  these  equa:ons  equal  and   then  solve  for  Q,  which  is  also  only  one  Q,  both  quan:ty  demanded  and  quan:ty   supplied.    We  find  that  the  quan:ty  that  both  buyers  and  sellers  want  to  trade  is  8   units  of  the  good.         Again,  we  plug  this  value  of  Q  in  any  of  the  original  equa:ons  to  find  the  equilibrium   price,  which  is  now  $5.6/unit.    I  do  this  subs:tu:on  in  both  equa:ons,  demand  and   supply,  to  show  again  that  the  result  is  the  same.    The  new  equilibrium  is  8  units  of   the  good  and  $5.6/unit.       16  
  • 17. 17  
  • 18. 18  
  • 19. Suppose  the  price  in  the  market  is  $4/unit.    The  amount  that  buyers  will  buy  at  that   price  is  10  units.    The  buyers’  total  benefit  (so-­‐called  “consumer”  benefit)  is  the  area   under  the  demand  curve  and  bound  by  the  quan:ty:  10  units.    Now,  the  buyers   spend  in  the  good:  P  Q  =  ($4/unit)  (10  units)  =  $40.    They  receive  the  10  units  of  the   good  that  yields  for  them  the  total  benefit.    However,  a  por:on  of  the  total  benefit  –   the  rectangle  represen:ng  their  expenditure  –  is  not  free.    They  pay  for  that.    S:ll,   there  is  the  triangle  above  the  expenditure  rectangle  for  which  buyers  pay  nothing.    It   is  their  net  benefit  or  “consumer  surplus.”    It  is  the  welfare  that  buyers  receive  for   free  from  the  amount  of  the  good  they  buy  from  the  sellers.    They  receive  this  net   benefit  or  “consumer  surplus”  because  the  market  exists  –  because  there  is  another   side  to  the  market,  because  there  are  sellers  willing  to  cooperate  or  trade  with  them.     This  is  the  source  of  the  consumer  surplus.     The  consumer  surplus  is  represented  by  the  area  of  that  triangle.    To  calculate  the   area,  we  use  the  formula  (b  h)/2.    In  this  case,  the  base  is  10  units  and  the  height  is   the  intercept  of  the  demand  curve  minus  the  price  in  the  market,  which  is  $4/unit.     Therefore,  it  is  12-­‐4  =  8,  mul:plied  by  10,  that  is  80,  and  80  divided  by  2  is  40.    Note   that  the  units  are  just  dollars:  $40.    The  values  on  the  ver:cal  axis  are  prices:  $/unit.     So  $12/unit  minus  $4/unit  =  $8/unit.    Now  when  you  mul:ply  $/unit  :mes  units,  the   units  cancel  out,  and  you  obtain  $,  just  plain  dollars.     19  
  • 20. 20  
  • 21. Let  us  now  calculate  the  producer  surplus.     Again,  if  the  price  in  the  market  is  $4/unit.    The  amount  that  sellers  will  sell  at  that   price  is  10  units.  Remember  that  the  height  of  the  supply  curve  indicates  the  lowest   price  that  sellers  ask  for  one  unit  of  the  good,  and  that  is  precisely  the  cost  of  the   good  for  them.    The  sellers’  total  receipts  or  revenues  are  P  Q  =  (4)  (10)  =  $40.    That  is   represented  by  this  rectangle.    The  area  below  the  supply  curve  and  bound  by  the   quan:ty:  10  units  is  the  cost  for  the  producers.  Note  that  the  sellers’  revenues  P  Q,   $40,  are  more  than  the  sellers’  cost.    The  difference  of  R  –  C  =  profit.    The  profit  is   also  called  the  “producer  surplus.”     The  consumer  surplus  is  represented  by  the  area  of  this  triangle.    Again,  the  area  is  (b   h)/2.    In  this  case,  the  base  is  10  units  and  the  height  is  the  market  price,  $4/unit,   minus  the  intercept  of  the  supply  curve,  $2/unit.    The  height  is  then  4-­‐2  =  $2/unit.     Therefore,  the  producer  surplus  is  (10)  (2)  =  20,  divided  by  2:  $10.       So,  the  net  welfare  benefit  of  the  sellers,  their  profit  or  producer  surplus,  is  a   measure  of  the  welfare  of  sellers  in  the  market  –  something  they  receive  for  free,   because  the  market  exists.    It  is  calculated  in  dollars.    It’s  $10.   21  
  • 22. The  total  surplus  or  the  net  welfare  benefit  that  the  buyers  and  sellers  receive   altogether  is  the  sum  of  the  consumer  and  the  producer  surpluses.   22  
  • 23. In  other  words,  the  total  surplus  is  equal  to  $40  +  $10  =  $50.     To  repeat:  This  is  a  measure  of  the  net  welfare  benefits  that  both  buyers  and  sellers   together  receive  as  a  result  of  the  existence  of  the  market,  which  is  to  say,  as  a  result   of  their  coopera:ng  with  each  other.    It’s  the  fruits  of  their  coopera:on,  which  –  in   this  par:cular  case  –  takes  the  form  of  trade.     And  to  keep  the  :me  of  this  videos  short,  there’s  no  summary.    You  can  go  back  and   replay  the  parts  that  you  may  need  to  study  more  carefully.     I  hope  this  was  helpful  to  you.    I’ll  see  you  in  class.   23