SlideShare uma empresa Scribd logo
1 de 25
Baixar para ler offline
The Empirical Law of Active Management
                   Perspectives on the Declining Skill of U.S. Fund Managers
                                                Edouard Senechal, CFA


                      Forthcoming Journal of Portfolio Management Fall 2010

Abstract:


This paper proposes a new analytical framework for assessing the breadth (or diversification) and skill

of a portfolio manager: the Empirical Law of Active Management. This framework requires no

assumption regarding the manager’s asset returns expectations or investment process. It generalizes

Grinold’s [1989] Fundamental Law of Active Management, and creates an analytical framework for

measuring skill and diversification in a consistent manner for large cross sections of funds. We applied

this framework to analyze the evolution of skill and diversification since 1980 for 2,798 U.S. mutual

funds and found that skill has been declining among U.S. mutual funds while diversification has been

increasing. We put forward two explanations for this decrease in skill. First, the growth in mutual fund

assets has made it more difficult for the industry as a whole to outperform the market. Second, our

analysis of the relationship between skill and diversification led us to conclude that the U.S. mutual

fund industry responded to an increase in the demand for its products by creating funds with less

information content.




This is the submitted version of the following article: “The Empirical Law of Active Management; Perspectives on the

Declining Skill of U.S. Fund Managers”, Edouard Sénéchal, Journal of Portfolio Management, Fall 2010, Copyright © 2010,

Institutional Investor, Inc. which will be published in its final form at: http://www.iijournals.com/toc/jpm/current


The author would like to thank Brian Singer for his encouragements, inputs and constructive critics, Russell Wermers for

helpful suggestions, Eugene Fama and the participants at the spring 2009 “Research Project: Finance” course at the

University of Chicago Booth School of Business, Edwin Denson, Greg Fedorinchick and Mabel Lung for helpful suggestions.




September, 2010                                                                                            1
The Fundamental Law of Active Management says that the information ratio of a portfolio is the

product of the skill of the manager in selecting securities and the breadth of the strategy. In this

construct, “skill” is measured by the correlation between the manager’s expected and realized

returns, and “breadth” is the square-root of the number of independent positions in the portfolio.

Grinold and Kahn [1999] state: “The Fundamental Law is designed to give us insight into active

management. It isn’t an operational tool.” nevertheless, the usefulness of these insights has led

practitioners to seek to make it an operational tool. The main advance in this direction were brought

by Clarke, de Silva and Thorley [2002], who introduced the concept of transfer coefficient1 to account

for the constraints that a manager faces when implementing a particular strategy. They also worked

out the application of the Fundamental Law to ex-post performance attribution. However, despite

these advances, the practical application of the Fundamental Law of Active Management remains

difficult.


Firstly, one needs to have access to the manager’s return expectations, which are hard to obtain. For

qualitatively-oriented managers, return expectations are not formalized in a way that allows the
                                                               2
computation of an information coefficient.                         Often quantitative managers will not make this

information available to external investors in order to avoid potential reverse engineering of the

manager’s investment process. Moreover, when assessing a manager, using information that can be

independently verified is always preferable.


Secondly, the Fundamental Law relies heavily on the assumption that managers follow the precepts of

the active portfolio management theory developed in Grinold and Kahn [1999]. Hence, applications of

the Fundamental Law to managers that do not follow these precepts will lead to questionable results.


Finally, by seeking to transform the Fundamental Law into an operational tool, researchers have also

made it more complex and difficult to interpret (See Clarke, de Silva and Thorley [2006] or Buckle

[2004]). One of the key advantages of the analytical framework proposed in this paper is the simplicity


                                                            
1
    The transfer coefficient is the correlation between optimal unconstrained portfolio weights and actual portfolio weights
2
    The information coefficient is the correlation between the manager expected returns and realized returns 




September, 2010                                                                                                 2
of its application. This approach only requires portfolio holdings and realized returns to analyze how

the breadth of the portfolio and the skill of a manager contribute to the information ratio of the

portfolio. It does not require any information regarding the manager’s expected returns or assumptions

with respect to the manager’s investment process.




A New Approach to Estimating Breadth: The Diversification Factor


The fact that the Fundamental Law is difficult to apply to many portfolios does not mean that it does

not apply. Indeed, the risk adjusted returns of a portfolio, no matter what the investment process is,

will always be a function of a manager’s skill and a strategy’s breadth. In order to apply the

Fundamental Law to a wider range of strategies, we sidestep the issues outlined in the introduction by

starting from portfolio weights rather than the manager’s expected alphas. The cornerstone of this

approach consists of computing what would be the information ratio (IR) of the portfolio if there were

no diversification benefits (i.e. if all positions in the portfolio were perfectly correlated). The

difference between the IR computed assuming that all positions are perfectly correlated and the actual

IR represents the benefits from diversification. On the other hand, the IR of the portfolio in the

absence of diversification benefits represents the skill of the manager.


If there were no benefit from portfolio diversification, the active risk of the portfolio would be the

position-weighted mean active volatility of the assets included in the portfolio3:


   wi i
           i




Where          wi is the weight of asset i and  i is the active volatility of asset i. The asset active volatility is

defined as the volatility of the return difference between the benchmark and the asset. Hence the

impact of diversification on the active risk of the portfolio can be measured by the ratio of the

position-weighted mean volatility (  ) and the actual portfolio active risk(  ). The higher the               

                                                            
3
    See appendix 1 for proof



September, 2010                                                                                     3
ratio is, the larger the impact of diversification. Hence, we define the diversification factor (DI) as

follows:


      
DI=
      
As a result, the active risk of a portfolio can be written as:

           

           DI
There are three elements that will affect the diversification of the portfolio: the number of positions,

the correlation between these positions and the concentration of assets’ weights and assets’

volatilities. The first element is fairly straightforward. More positions mean more diversification.

However, not all positions bring the same level of diversification. Adding highly correlated positions to

the portfolio creates little diversification. Hence, the second element that impacts the diversification

of the portfolio is the level of correlation among the positions in the portfolio. The concentration of

the weights in the portfolio will also impact the diversification factor. Indeed, if we consider a

portfolio where one position’s weight is 20 times the weight of all the other positions, the

diversification of this portfolio will be lower than that of a similar portfolio where all positions are

equally weighted. The same logic applies to volatilities. If one asset’s volatility is 20 times that of the

other assets, the portfolio return will be highly dependent on the outcome of this one bet and its

diversification will be lower than if all volatilities were equal. Concentration of positions’ weights and

concentration of positions’ volatilities have the same impact on diversification. They both reduce it by

making the portfolio more dependent on fewer positions. We regroup these two variables into one

variable, the concentration of the risk-weights (where risk-weights for position i is equal to ( wi i )      ).

We show in appendix 1 that the portfolio diversification can be written as a function of these three

factors:


                        DI=
                                      1             (Equation 1)
                               1
                                    n  (i )
                               n




September, 2010                                                                             4
Where:


              n is the number of positions in the portfolio

                  is roughly a risk-weighted average correlation among the positions in the portfolios4

              i is the risk-weight of position i, (i.e. i  (wi i )    )


               (i ) is        the standard deviation of the risk weights across the portfolio, measuring the

              concentration in the portfolio.

The diversification factor can be interpreted as a number of positions. Let’s illustrate this point with

the example of a portfolio that contains ten positions, where the active returns of these positions are

independent and each position has an equal risk-weight of 10%. In this example,                  =  ( ) =0   and

therefore it follows from equation (1) that the diversification of the portfolio is 10. Hence, for any

portfolio, diversification represents the equivalent number of independent positions with equal risk-

weights.




A New Approach to Estimating Skill


To assess the impact of diversification on the risk-adjusted returns of a portfolio, we need to divide the

numerator and the denominator of the information ration by  :


              
IR          *                              DI
              

                                                                                       
Where         is the active return of the portfolio. Then we define the quantity          as the skill (SK) of the
                                                                                       
manager which yields:


IR  SK * DI


                                                            
4
    see exact formula in appendix 1 




September, 2010                                                                                   5
The Empirical Law of Active Management expresses exactly the same fact as the Fundamental Law,

namely, that IR is a product of skill and diversification. However, using the Empirical Law, we do not

need to make any assumptions about the way in which the portfolio is constructed. The only

information that is required to analyze the skill and diversification of the manager is a portfolio’s

holdings and realized returns.


Skill in the context of the Empirical Law represents the ability of the manager to allocate its risk-

capital to securities with high risk-adjusted returns. To demonstrate this point, we need to observe

that the portfolio alpha is also the weighted average alpha of each security in the portfolio (i.e.

   wi i ). Then we can express skill as the risk-weighted average of the information ratios of the
            i


individual positions in the portfolio:
                                       i
            
                      w    i    i
SK                     i                 i
                                                 i IRi
                                                i




Where IRi is the information ratio of position i and                       i its   risk-weight. In this framework, skill

represents the ability of the manager to select securities that have a strong information ratio on a

stand-alone basis. In other words, it is a measure of the manager’s ability to maximize the risk-

adjusted returns of the portfolio without using the benefit of risk diversification. It is important to note

that in the Empirical Law, the skill coefficient is defined more broadly than the information coefficient

of the Fundamental Law. Whereas the information coefficient measures the pure stock picking ability

of the manager, the skill factor, in addition to stock picking, also incorporates the impact of portfolio

concentration and the size of the manager’s opportunity. We can illustrate this point by examining the

covariance between the risk-weights and the information ratio:5



        
    ~ ~ 1
             n i
                     
                 ~ ~ 1
                            n i
                                 ~ 1   
Cov  , IR  ~  i * IRi  ~  i  * ~  IRi
                                        n i
                                             ~
                                                               

                                                            
5
    Note that this decomposition was inspired by Andrew Lo’s AP decomposition. See proposition 1 in Lo [2007]



September, 2010                                                                                                 6
~              ~
Where    i       and IRi are the risk weights and information ratios of each of the securities in the

manager’s investment universe and             ~
                                              n is the number of securities in the investment universe. We
define investment universe as the entire set of securities in which the manager can invest. (The ~

denotes that the variable covers the entire universe as opposed to securities included in the portfolio

only.) By including all the securities in the manager’s universe in our covariance computation, we can

fully capture the relation between risk-weights and information ratios. Indeed, securities that are in

the manager universe but not in the portfolio do not directly contribute to the risk adjusted return of

the portfolio; however, they do contain information with respect to the manager’s stock-picking skill.


                                                                                                  IR   0 .
                                                                                                      ~
Given that the universe is a passive and information-less portfolio, we can assume that                i
                                                                                                  i



                                                                                * IR is our skill factor.
                                                                                 ~     ~
The expectation of the risk-weights and information ratio products:                i     i
                                                                               i


Hence, we can re-write the skill of the manager in function of the covariance between securities risk

weights and information ratios:               ~     ~ ~
                                         SK  n Cov( , IR 

              ~                              ~
Finally, if   n is large enough so that   IR )  1, we obtain:

        ~ ~ ~ ~
SK   ( , IR n   )

This decomposition of the skill factor is helpful to understand the three elements that are important in

determining the skill of a manager:


                      ~     ~
                   ( , IR  :   The correlation between risk-weights and securities information ratios is

                   similar to the information coefficient in the Fundamental Law; it represents the ability of

                   the manager to pick-securities.

                  ~
                   n : The size of the universe of securities that the manager will analyze. It represents the
                   opportunity set from which the manager can create value added for his clients.

                     ~
                     ) : A measure of the portfolio concentration. This parameter illustrates the fact that

                   a more concentrated portfolio will better leverage the manager’s stock picking ability.



September, 2010                                                                              7
This last point illustrates the fact that diversification also forces managers to go down the list of their

investment ideas and implement positions with less expected return.




Comparison of the Fundamental and Empirical Laws


The Empirical Law and Fundamental Law possess two key differences. First, the Empirical Law side

steps the concepts of information coefficient and transfer coefficient. The skill of a manager depends

on the relation between risk-weight and risk-adjusted performance (see Exhibit 1). As we discussed in

the introduction, for manager-of-managers, the information necessary to compute a transfer

coefficient or information coefficient is not available. In practice, fundamental managers cannot

cleanly separate transfer coefficient and breadth. The concept of TC makes sense for quantitative

managers using models that provide expected returns on wide ranges of securities irrespective of

whether they can be implemented or not. On the other hand, given the cost of bottom-up research,

fundamental analysts focus on trades that can be implemented. In an investment firm that runs long

only portfolios, one rarely sees analysts spending much time on overvalued assets. This makes the

distinction between transfer coefficient and diversification less meaningful for fundamental managers.




Exhibit 1: Information Triangle

                                                       Fundamental Law
                                                       Empirical Law
                  Manager Proprietary Information

                                 Ex‐ante Alphas



                       Information                 Transfer 
                        Coefficient               Coefficient




        Performance                       SK                    Portfolio  Positions
                                                                (or Risk –Weights)
                             Public Information for
                             Traditional Funds
       This diagram is inspired from Figure 1 of Clarke de Silva Thorley (2002).




September, 2010                                                                           8
Therefore, the Empirical Law does not distinguish between the two. If a position is not in the portfolio,

we do not seek to know if this is due to lack of breadth or poor transfer coefficient. However, given

access to the unconstrained optimal weights of a quantitative manager, we have the flexibility to

reintroduce the concept of transfer coefficient. By recomputing the manager IR, DI and SK with these

optimal weights (noted IR*, DI* and SK*), we can define our transfer coefficient as:6


             IR
TC              , which yields IR  TC * SK * DI
                                            *     *
               *
            IR

The second key difference between the two approaches is that the Fundamental Law makes the

assumption that the portfolio manager uses a mean variance optimization to construct the portfolio.

The Empirical Law does not rely on any formal assumption regarding the manager’s portfolio

construction process, and uses the fund’s IR as the yardstick of a manager’s success.




Can you get indigestion from the diversification free lunch?


Warren Buffett has observed that “Diversification is a protection against ignorance. It makes very little

sense for those who know what they're doing.”7 Indeed, diversification forces the skilled manager to

reduce the portfolio’s concentration in the positions with the highest expected return in order to

reduce risk. If one has perfect foresight there is no risk, and there is little to be gained in reducing risk

through diversification. However, for investment managers with less than perfect foresight

diversification makes a lot of sense. As we noted previously, while diversification also forces portfolio

managers to add to the portfolio positions with decreasing risk-adjusted return.


Moreover, bottom-up stock picking requires specialized knowledge in the securities being analyzed.

Thus far, we have implicitly assumed that skill is a fixed quantity that is inherent to the investment

process and can be leveraged into as many trades as one can implement. While this somewhat reflects
                                                            
6
    Note than in theory this TC can be greater than one. Since the objective function that produces the optimal weights of the

manager is not necessarily the IR, it is conceivable that the constrained IR be greater than the unconstrained IR.
7
    Source: http://en.wikiquote.org/wiki/Warren_Buffett         



September, 2010                                                                                                9
the way quantitative managers create value, for fundamental managers more diversification means less

depth of research. Therefore, a fixed SK coefficient does not reflect the tradeoff between quality of

coverage (or depth) and breadth of coverage, which fundamental managers do face. Fundamental

managers could leverage their SK factor across other trades only if they hire more analysts of the same

quality; however, producing a good analyst is costly and/or time-consuming. In the long term, it is

feasible to grow a research team, but there are usually increased inefficiencies that come with larger

organizations.8


Concentration also has negative consequences for risk adjusted returns. The most obvious disadvantage

of concentration is that it will result in a higher risk. Hence, the optimal balance between

diversification and skill also depends on the client ability to take risk and to diversify this risk. For

institutional investors with long investment horizons and the resources to effectively detect skillful

managers, diversification is relatively cheap to obtain. In theory, such investors should seek

concentrated portfolios where skill is not diluted by diversification. For retail investors who have to

support higher transaction costs and cannot perform extensive due diligence, investing in few

diversified portfolios makes more sense. For a given fund size, more concentration will automatically

result in less liquid positions, which, everything else being equal, will have a negative impact on

performance.9




Empirical Analysis of the Relation between Diversification and Skill


Two empirical studies have found that mutual funds with high levels of concentration tend to

outperform funds with lower levels of concentration. Kacperczyk et al.[2005, 2007] found that small-


                                                            
8
    Chen et al. [2004], find results consistent with this view. They observe that small sized funds outperform large sized funds and

argue that part of this difference in performance is due to organizational diseconomies related to hierarchy costs.



9
    See Becker and Vaughan [2001] for illustration of this point, see also Chen et al. [2004] who find that a key variable to explain

difference in performance between small funds and large funds is liquidity. 




September, 2010                                                                                                   10
cap funds with higher levels of industry concentration were generating greater alpha than funds with

lower levels of industry concentration. Cremers and Petajisto [2008] measured the fund concentration

with its active share and found that funds with high concentration outperformed funds with low

concentration. The measures of concentration used in these two studies focus on the concentration of

portfolio weights. Unlike the DI coefficient these measures of concentration do not capture the impact
                                                                                                                  10
of concentration in positions’ volatilities and correlations among positions.


In order to understand the relation between portfolio diversification and skill, we applied the Empirical

Law of Active Management to a universe of 2,798 U.S. mutual funds invested in domestic equities from

1980 to 2006. The first obstacle we faced in assessing the skill of a manager was defining the

benchmark. While the concept of benchmark is ubiquitous in today’s asset management industry, it

was not the case in the 80’s and early 90’s. Hence, finding an accurate and consistent definition of a

fund’s benchmark across all periods is difficult. Moreover, the active returns of a fund measured

against its stated benchmark often contain common factor bets such as value, size or momentum that

can distort the active returns coming purely from stock picking skills. For these reasons, we used factor

models to determine the appropriate benchmark. We labeled as alpha or active return any returns that

could not be explained by the factors of the model we used. Therefore, the choice of model and the

factors that we included in the model were critical. Our objective was to assess the stock-picking skill

of a manager, as a result all known “priced factors” should be included in our model and excluded from

the manager’s alpha. “Priced factors” are factors for which empirical studies have demonstrated the

existence of positive risk adjusted returns; namely: market, value, size and momentum. To assess a

fund’s exposure to these factors, we used the same four-factor model as Carhart [1997]. In order to

ensure that our results were not dependent on the model, we also used two alternative models that

are based on similar factors but that use different techniques to assess the exposures. The first
                                                            
                                                                w                                    
10
     Kacperczyk et al. define as industry concentration as:         portfolio
                                                                                 wimarket portfolio
                                                                                                       2   (where wi is the weight of industry i in the
                                                                   i
                                                               i


portfolio and in the market portfolio). Cremers and Petajisto use active share, which, is the sum of the absolute deviations of the


portfolio weights from the benchmark weights. Active Share        w i
                                                                                i
                                                                                 portfolio
                                                                                              wibenchmark




September, 2010                                                                                                                   11
alternative model is based on the characteristic based benchmarks developed by Daniel et al. [1997].
                                                                                                                             11
The second alternative model is based on the 25 Fama-French portfolios sorted on value and size.

(See appendix 2 for a more precise description of the models and the data).


Exhibit 2 shows the average alpha, skill, diversification and number of securities per fund across each

of the periods we examined. Alpha and skill are net of the funds’ expenses ratios. The decline in

mutual fund alphas that we observed in this table was very important. The average mutual fund in our

universe went from generating a 29 bps positive alpha in the first part of the a 90’s to a negative 1.3%

alpha in the second part of the 90’s. This trend is consistent with the four-factor alphas reported by

Kosowski et al. [2006] for similar periods and is also reported by Fama and French [2009]. Such

variations in the average alpha and skill of mutual fund managers are surprising considering that since

the 1990’s, the Investment Company Institute (ICI) has reported a decline in U.S. mutual fund expense

ratios.12 The second interesting trend that we observed in Exhibit 2 was a general increase in the
                                                                                                          13
number of positions per portfolio and therefore in the diversification of the funds.                           This increase in

portfolio diversification among mutual fund managers is consistent with the inroads that modern

portfolio theory made during the 80’s and 90’s among practitioners and the development of passive

mutual funds. In addition, this period also witnessed a significant development of information

technology solutions that drastically reduced the operational costs of running portfolios with a large

number of positions.




Exhibit 2: Number of Funds, Mean Alpha, Skill, Diversification and number of positions per
portfolio for each Period.
The benchmark of each portfolio is estimated with the

Carhart [1997] model.



                                                            
11
     See Daniel et al. [1997] and Wermers [2004] for more details on DGTW portfolio. The DGTW benchmarks are available via

http://www.smith.umd.edu/faculty/rwermers/ftpsite/Dgtw/coverpage.htm. The Fama-French portfolio are available via:

http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/data_library.html
12
     See: Investment Company Institute Research Department Staff [2009] and Collins [2009]
13
     Cremers and Petajisto [2009] report similar results using active share. 




September, 2010                                                                                                12
Number of                                           Number of 
 Period           Funds           Alpha         SK             DI   Positions
 1980‐1984         137            0.58%       0.007            36      71
 1985‐1989         270            0.43%       0.004            45      84
 1990‐1994         588            0.29%       0.001            62      96
 1995‐1999        1519           ‐1.28%       ‐0.013           65     125
 2000‐2006        2378           ‐1.28%       ‐0.008           70     148
 1980‐2006        2798           ‐0.84%       ‐0.007           63     135



We see two non-exclusive explanations for the decline in skill that we observed among equity mutual

funds. First, mutual fund managers were victims of their own success. The net asset value of equity

mutual funds as a percentage of the capitalization of the U.S. stock market increased from 3% to 40%

between 1980 and 200814. If mutual fund managers are a representative sample of the equity market

investors, Sharpe’s [1991] arithmetic of active management entails that as a whole, mutual fund

managers should have a negative alpha roughly equal to the fees they charge. As the industry grows

closer to representing the U.S. stock market, it is more difficult for the industry as a whole to

outperform the market.


              The second explanation for this phenomenon is that the quality of U.S. Equity mutual funds has

declined. The industry would have responded to the increase in demand for mutual funds that took

place during the 80’s and 90’s by creating sub-par products. The market for asset management

services, like the Lemons market described by Akerlof [1970], is characterized by an asymmetry of

information.15 Since it is difficult for investors to distinguish a skilled from an unskilled manager, there

is a large incentive for unskilled managers to flood the market and distribute low cost investment

strategies that add no value while charging active management fees. This incentive is even greater

when demand expands and new customers with less financial acumen enter the market. Under such

circumstances, unskilled managers, or “closet indexers”, will want to take the minimum level of risk

that allows them to charge active management fees. On the other hand, skilled managers have an

incentive to take relatively more concentrated positions. Such situations should result in a positive


                                                            
14
     To compute these percentages, we used net asset value of equity mutual funds reported in the 2009 Investment Company Fact

Book (Investment Company Institute Research Department Staff [2009]) and the Wilshire 5000 index capitalization as a proxy for

the capitalization of the U.S. stock market.
15
     See Foster and Young [2008]               



September, 2010                                                                                            13
skew in the distribution of alphas because skilled managers with concentrated portfolios will generate

high alphas, while unskilled managers will generate moderate negative alphas. Under this hypothesis,

the industry responded to an increasing demand for mutual funds by increasing its “lemon” production

and crafting strategies with little information content and with the look and feel of effective active

investment strategies. In order to assess this hypothesis, we examined the cross-sectional relation

between skill and diversification by splitting our universe of mutual funds into quintiles of

diversification and compared the skill of the funds located in each quintile.


Exhibit 3: Alpha and Skill by Quintiles of Diversification
The benchmark of each portfolio is estimated with the Carhart [1997] model.


                                                               Skill by Diversification(DI) Quintile (1980‐2006)

                                                      Quintile 1:                                           Quintile 5: 
                                                      Low DI        Quintile 2   Quintile 3   Quintile 4    High DI
Mean                                                     0.004         ‐0.007       ‐0.011       ‐0.011        ‐0.011
T‐stat (Mean Skill)                                       2.02          ‐6.34       ‐10.77      ‐11.98         ‐14.50
Skill Difference : Quintile 1 ‐ Quintile 2,3,4 or 5                    0.012        0.016        0.015         0.015
T‐stat (Skill Difference)                                                4.78        6.45          6.50          6.51
Standard Deviation                                        0.05           0.03        0.02         0.02          0.02
Skewness                                                  0.97          ‐0.21        0.15         ‐0.51         ‐0.62
Kurtosis                                                  7.06           5.03        5.17         4.46          4.98
Number of Observations                                    560            559         560           559           560




In Exhibit 3, we observe that funds located in the first diversification quintile did exhibit significantly

more skill than any of the other quintiles. On average, the skill of these funds was greater than zero

while the skill in all the other quintiles of the distribution was significantly less than zero. All the

differences in skill between quintile 1 and each of the four other quintiles are statistically significant.


Exhibit 3 also indicates a positive skew in the distribution of the skill of low diversification portfolio

managers. This fact indicates that our result could be explained by survivorship bias. Less

diversification implies more risk. Since we required at least 36 months of returns to include a fund in

our analysis, it is possible that the low diversification funds that severely underperformed rapidly lost

their clients and did not survive long enough to be included in our analysis. Note that the positive skew

in the distribution of alpha can be explained by factors other than survivorship bias. As we observed

earlier, the presence of closet indexers or “lemons” in the mutual fund market is consistent with such

distribution of alphas.


September, 2010                                                                                                            14
In order to test the impact of a possible survivorship bias on our results, we created an artificial bias

against the top performing funds by eliminating funds in the right tail of the alpha distribution in order

to have a symmetric distribution. We removed from our analysis all funds whose alpha was greater than

the absolute value of the first percentile of the alpha distribution.




After removing these funds, the skew of the distribution became slightly negative; however, the skill

difference between the first quintile of managers and the rest of the universe remained strongly

significant (see top-panel of exhibit 4). In order to further test the robustness of our results, we

designed a more conservative artificial survivorship bias, where we removed all funds with alpha

greater than the absolute value of the fifth percentile of the alpha distribution. Under this definition of

the artificial survivorship bias, we eliminated from our sample all the funds with annualized alpha

greater than 6.7% per annum. Nevertheless, the bottom panel of exhibit 4 shows that low

diversification funds still exhibited significantly higher skill under both definitions of the artificial

survivorship bias. Hence, the relationship that we observed between skill and diversification cannot be

explained away by survivorship bias.




Exhibit 4: Alpha and Skill by Diversification Quintiles From 1980 to 2006 Excluding top Performing
Funds
Out-performing funds are funds with an alpha greater than the absolute value of the first or fifth percentile of the alpha
distribution. The benchmark of each portfolio is estimated with the Carhart model.

                                                                                  Skill by Diversification(DI) Quintile (1980‐2006) Excluding Top‐
                                                                                                          Performing Funds 

                                                                                Quintile 1:                                            Quintile 5: 
                                                                                Low DI        Quintile 2   Quintile 3    Quintile 4    High DI
                          Mean                                                     ‐0.001       ‐0.009        ‐0.011        ‐0.011        ‐0.010
 Absolute Value of 1st 




                          T‐stat (Mean Skill)                                       ‐0.48        ‐7.55        ‐11.27        ‐12.40        ‐14.27
                          Skill Difference : Quintile 1 ‐ Quintile 2,3,4 or 5                    0.008        0.011         0.010         0.010
 Percentile Alpha
 Alpha less than 




                          T‐stat (Skill Difference)                                              3.61           5.10          5.18          4.94
                          Standard Deviation                                        0.04         0.03          0.02          0.02          0.02
                          Skewness                                                  ‐0.04        ‐0.46         ‐0.18         ‐0.54         ‐0.63
                          Kurtosis                                                  5.35         4.62           3.97          4.43          5.00
                          Number of Observations                                     554          554           554           554           554
                          Mean                                                     ‐0.007        ‐0.01        ‐0.012        ‐0.011        ‐0.011
 Absolute Value of 5th 




                          T‐stat (Mean Skill)                                       ‐4.08        ‐9.28        ‐11.62        ‐12.62        ‐14.53
                          Skill Difference : Quintile 1 ‐ Quintile 2,3,4 or 5                    0.003        0.005         0.005         0.004
 Percentile Alpha
 Alpha less than 




                          T‐stat (Skill Difference)                                              1.80           2.73          2.58          2.31
                          Standard Deviation                                        0.04         0.03          0.02          0.02          0.02
                          Skewness                                                  ‐0.59        ‐0.60         ‐0.27         ‐0.55         ‐0.84
                          Kurtosis                                                  5.53         4.31           3.85          4.42          4.49
                          Number of Observations                                     543          542           543           542           543




September, 2010                                                                                                                                       15
The relation between skill and diversification also held across the three different types of models that

we used to define the alpha for the 1980-2006 period. Exhibit 5 also shows strongly significant results if

we use the characteristic based benchmarks or the 25 Fama-French portfolios to establish the alpha of

each fund. However, the relationship between skill and diversification was not consistent across

periods. Breaking up the 1980-2006 periods into 5 distinct sub-periods, we did not find that low

diversification funds outperformed in each sub-period (see exhibit 5). We did not find any significant

relation between diversification and skill during the eighties and the early nineties.




Exhibit 5: Relation between Skill and Diversification across periods and models
For each period and each model, we show the mean of the t-stats for the differences in skill between quintile one and quintiles
two to five (Mean t-stat). We also show the smallest of the four t-stats (Min t-stat). For the Carhart model in the period 1980-
2006, we can read from table 3 that the four t-stats are 4.78, 6.45, 6.50 and 6.51. The mean of these four t-stats: 6.06 and
minimum: 4.78 are displayed in the top left cell of table 5. FF-25 denotes the results that we obtained with the 25 Fama-French
portfolios, DGTW indicate that we used the characteristic based benchmarks of Daniel et al. [1997]




                                            1980            2000            1995            1990            1985            1980       
                                              to              to              to              to              to              to         
                               Periods:     2006            2006            1999            1994            1989            1984
                        Mean t‐stat          6.06            7.46            2.11           ‐0.40           0.68            ‐0.28
       Carhart          Min t‐stat           4.78            6.90            1.84           ‐0.64           0.07            ‐0.71
                        Mean t‐stat          3.59            2.23            4.08            0.86           ‐0.57           ‐1.52
        DGTW            Min t‐stat           1.95            1.78            2.54            0.50           ‐2.26           ‐1.98
                        Mean t‐stat          4.29            3.15            5.33            0.91           1.15            ‐1.03
        FF‐25           Min t‐stat           3.66            1.75            4.50            0.04           0.20            ‐1.25
Number of Observations per Quintile         559.6           475.6           303.8           117.6            54             27.6




Since we could not find a significant relation between diversification and skill in every sub-period, we

found it difficult to conclude that concentrated managers had an intrinsic advantage over less

concentrated managers. Instead, the result of this study is better interpreted using Lo’s [2004]

Adaptative Market Hypothesis. The ability of U.S. mutual funds to beat the market evolved through

time under the influence of the structure of the U.S. market for mutual funds. Our interpretation of

these results is based on two elements. First, concentration among mutual fund managers has

decreased since the 80’s. Second, our analysis shows that since the mid-90’s, skill was more likely to

be found in more concentrated portfolios. These two points taken together indicated that as the

demand for mutual funds increased, the industry responded by producing funds with higher

diversification but lower information content, also known as “closet-indexers.” As a result, the average




September, 2010                                                                                                                             16
skill and alpha of U.S. equity mutual funds decreased. In most industries, increases in demand are met

by increases in price; however, no such price increase took place in the asset management industry

during the 90’s.16 We infer from our data that the asset management industry took advantage of this

increase in demand by cutting the information content of its products while leaving its management

fees unchanged.




Conclusion

The Fundamental Law of Active Management played a very important role in the development of

quantitative asset management. The application of this law was designed by quantitative investment

managers for quantitative investment managers, and is difficult to apply to other types of processes.

However, the result of the Fundamental Law of Active Management applies to all investment managers.

The Empirical Law of Asset Management presented in this paper seeks to generalize and extend this

tool to a wider range of portfolios while conserving the key insights that made this concept a success.


The application of this analytical framework to U.S. equity mutual funds reveals a general decline in

skill. We found two explanations for this decrease in skill. Firstly, the mutual fund industry was a

victim of its own success, as mutual funds represent a greater share of the market capitalization. It is

now close to impossible for the industry as a whole to outperform the market. Secondly, the decrease

in skill was accompanied by an increase in diversification. Since the mid-90’s, we also observe an

inverse relationship between skill and diversification. We suggest that the increase in diversification

does reflect a decrease in the quality of the information content of U.S. mutual funds.




                                                            
16
     See: Investment Company Institute Research Department Staff [2009]



September, 2010                                                                           17
References:


Akerlof, George. “The Market for "Lemons": Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism.” The
Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 84, No. 3 (1970), pp. 488-500.

Beckers, Stan, G. Vaughan. “Small is Beautiful.” Journal of Portfolio Management, Vol. 27, No. 4
(2001), pp. 9-17.

Berk, Jonathan, R. Green. “Mutual Fund Flows and Performance in Rational Markets.” Journal of
Political Economy, Vol. 112, No. 6 (2004), pp. 1269-1295.

Buckle, David. “How to calculate breadth: An evolution of the Fundamental Law of Active
Management.” Journal of Asset Management, Vol. 4, No. 6 (2004), pp. 393-405.

Daniel, Kent, M. Grinblatt, S. Titman and R. Wermers. “Measuring Mutual Fund Performance with
Characteristic Based Benchmarks.” The Journal of Finance, Vol. 52, No. 3 (1997), pp. 1035-1058.

 Carhart, Mark M. “On Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance.” The Journal of Finance, Vol. 52, No. 1
(1997), pp. 57-82.

Chen, Joseph, H. Hong, M. Huang and J. Kubik. “Does Fund Size Erode Mutual Fund Performance? The
Role of Liquidity and Organization.” The American Economic Review, Vol. 94, No. 5 (2004), pp. 1276-
1302.

Clarke, Roger, H. de Silva, S. Thorley. “Portfolio Constraints and the Fundamental Law of Active
Management.” Financial Analysts Journal, September/October 2002, Vol. 58, No. 5 (2002), pp. 48-66.

“The Fundamental Law of Active Portfolio Management.” Journal of Investment Management, Vol. 4,
No. 3 (2006), pp. 54–72.

Collins, Sean. “Trends in the Fees and Expenses of Mutual Funds, 2008.” Investment Company Institute
Research Fundamentals, Vol. 18, No. 3 (April 2009)

Cremers, Martjin, A. Petajisto “How Active is Your Fund Manager? A New Measure that Predicts
Performance.” Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 22, No. 9 (September 2009), pp. 3329-3365.

Foster, Dean, P. Young. “The Hedge Fund Game: Incentives, Excess Returns, and Performance Mimics.”
University of Oxford, Discussion Paper Series (2008).

Grinold, Richard C. “The Fundamental Law of Active Management.” The Journal of Portfolio
Management, Vol. 15, No. 3 (Spring 1989), pp. 30-37.

Grinold, Richard C., R. Kahn. Active Portfolio Management: A Quantitative Approach for Producing
Superior Returns and Controlling Risk, 2nd ed. McGraw-Hill, 1999.

Investment Company Institute Research Department Staff, “2009 Investment Company Fact Book”, 49th
Edition, (2009).

Kacperczyk, Marcin T., C. Sialm, L. Zheng. “On Industry concentration of Actively Managed Equity
Mutual Funds.” The Journal of Finance, 60 (2005), pp. 1983-2012.

Kacperczyk, Marcin T., C. Sialm, L. Zheng. “Industry Concentration and Mutual Fund Performance.”
Journal of Investment Management, Vol. 5, No. 1 (2007)

Kosowski, Robert, A. Timmermann, R. Wermers, A. White. “Can Mutual fund “Stars” Really Pick Stocks?
New Evidence from a Bootstrap Analysis.” Journal of Finance, Vol. 51, No. 6 (2006), pp. 2551-2595.



September, 2010                                                                        18
Fama, Eugene, K. French. “Luck versus Skill in the Cross Section of Mutual Fund Alpha Estimates.”
working paper (2009)

Lo, Andrew. “Risk management for hedge funds: introduction and overview.” Financial Analysts
Journal, Vol. 57, No. 6 (November/December 2001), pp.16-33.

“The Adaptive Markets Hypothesis: Market Efficiency from an Evolutionary Perspective.” Journal of
Portfolio Management, 30 (2004), pp. 15-29.

“Where Do Alphas Come From?: A New Measure of the Value of Active Investment Management.”
Journal of Investment Management, forthcoming.

Sharpe, William. “The Arithmetic of Active Management” Financial Analysts Journal, Vol. 47, No. 1
(January/February 1991), pp. 7-9.

Shleifer, Andrei, R. Vishny. “The Limits of Arbitrage.” The Journal of Finance, Vol. 52, No. 1 (1997),
pp. 35-55.

Pollet, Joshua, M. Wilson. “How Does Size Affect Fund Behavior?” working paper (2007).

Van Nieuwerburgh, Stijn, L. Veldkamp. “Information Acquisition and Under-Diversification.” working
paper (2008).

Wermers, Russ. “Are Mutual Fund Shareholders Compensated for Active Management "Bets"?” working
paper (2003).

“Is Money Really 'Smart'? New Evidence on the Relation Between Mutual Fund Flows, Manager Behavior,
and Performance Persistence.” working paper (2004).




September, 2010                                                                          19
Appendix 1: derivation of the Empirical Law of Active Management


wi is the weight of security i in the portfolio


w is the vector of all the securities weights in the portfolio.


 is the covariance matrix of the securities’ active return. If V is a classic covariance matrix of assets
returns of size (n x n), and B is a (n x n) matrix which contains n times the (n x1) vector of benchmark

weights and I is the identity matrix then  can be obtained in the following way:   ( I                       B)'V ( I  B)

. 17 The active variance of the portfolio ( w' w ) can be decomposed into the risk of the portfolio if all

securities were perfectly correlated and a second term which represents the benefits from

diversification.


w' w   wi2 i2   wi w j  i j  i , j
            i                 i   j i

w' w   w    wi w j  i j (1   i , j  1)
                 2
                 i   i
                      2

            i                 i   j i



                          2
                 
w' w    wi i    wi w j  i j (1   i , j )
         i          i j i



We separated the risk of the portfolio into two parts: First, the average volatility, which is the risk if

all positions were perfectly correlated. And second, the diversification benefits, which is the decrease

in risk due to positions in the portfolio being less than perfectly correlated.


Let’s note the average risk of a position in the portfolio as:



                                                            
17
   The I  B matrix contains n columns of active weights for n portfolios that are fully invested in one and only one asset:


     1          0 ... 0  w1b            w1b ... w1b 
     0                         b                   b
                 1 ... 0  w2
                                                                                          
                                             b
                                           w2 ... w2 
I B                                                  w1active w2 ... wn
                                                                     active active
     ...        ... ... ...  ...        ... ... ... 
                             b                    b
     0          0 ... 1  wn            wn ... wn 
                                             b
                                                       


September, 2010                                                                                               20
   wi i
               i




                                                     wi i
Let’s note risk weights: i                                           with these notations the active variance of a portfolio is:
                                                        

                                      2
                
w' w     i     2 i j (  i , j  1)
         i         i j i



We can re-write the active variance of the portfolio in the following way:


                                                   
w' w   2   2    i  j  i , j    i  j 
                                                   
                   i j i               i j i     

Or:


                                                
w' w   2 1    i  j  i , j    i  j 
                                                
                i j i               i j i     


The term             
                   i   j i
                                  i       j    i , j    i j can be broken down into two components:
                                                    i       j i




-       the product of the risk weights =                                        
                                                                                    i       j i
                                                                                                    i   j                                 (Equation 1)


-       risk weighted correlation =                           
                                                              i        j i
                                                                                i       j   i, j                                         (Equation 2)


We can rewrite equation 1 as:                                            1   
                                                                   i     j i
                                                                                    i       j
                                                                                                    i
                                                                                                            i
                                                                                                                j i
                                                                                                                       j
                                                                                                                           i
                                                                                                                               i   i   which can be expressed in


function of the variance of the risk weights:


                                                                                                            2
                                                                          1                        1
 i j   i  i2   i    i  
    i   j i                  i                         i                 n                        n

                                                                                        2
                   1              1        1       1
i i j  1    n 2     i  n    2 n  i  n 
i j            i       i
                              
                                          i             


September, 2010                                                                                                                                  21
2
                 1            1
i  i j  1  n     i  n 
i j                 i          


                                                   n 1
  
     i           j i
                               i       j       
                                                     n
                                                         n * Variance(i )


Hence the concentration of the risk weights is a direct function of the variance of the risk weights:


                                                                       n 1
   i  j  nVar ( i ) 
             i          j i                                             n

The higher the dispersion of the risk weights (that is the dispersion of portfolio weights and

volatilities), the higher the active risk of the portfolio. The second element of this diversification term

is the correlations among the positions of the portfolio (equation 2).


     i        j i
                                   i       j    i, j   i   j  i, j
                                                         i      j i




We note  i the average correlation of asset i with the other assets in the portfolio, weighted by the

                                                                                              18
risk-weight of each asset in the portfolio.



          i    j  i , j hence we obtain:   i j  i , j    i  i
                 ~
                           j i                                                   i   j i                 i




We call this quantity the risk weighted correlation:                                                                
                                                                                                                   i
                                                                                                                           i   i
                                                                                                                                   i   j i
                                                                                                                                              i   j   i, j




If we put everything back together:


                                n2  1       1                
w' w   2 1    nVar ( ) 
                                         2     nVar ( ) 
                                       
                                  n          n                
                                                            
18
     Note that the sum of the risk-weights excluding asset i does not add-up to one. The correct weighted average should be:


i  
                               j
                                               i , j The correlation term becomes:            (1   ) 
                                                                                                   i   i       i        
                 j  i (1  i )                                                              i




September, 2010                                                                                                                                              22
The diversification factor of the portfolio is defined as:


                                                                              1
                                                               DI 
                                                                      1             ~
                                                                           nVar ( i )
                                                                      n

Appendix 2:


The mutual funds quarterly holdings were obtained from the Thomson-Reuters mutual fund database.

The funds monthly returns were gathered from the CRSP mutual fund database and the securities’

returns were obtained from the CRSP U.S. Stock database. We used the MF Link mapping developed by

Russ Wermers to map funds in the Thomson-Reuters database to funds in the CRSP database.


We examined separately 6 periods: 1980-1984, 1985-1989, 1990-1994, 1995-1999, 2000-2006 and 1980-

2006. To be included in the analysis of a period a fund should have at least 36 months of returns during

that period. For each period, we used the following steps to compute the diversification and skill

factors. First we computed the return of each fund by taking the asset-weighted average return of all

share-classes. If a share-class asset value was missing on a given date, we took the equal-weighted

average return of all the share classes.


Second, we assessed the fund benchmark using each of the following three pricing models: the four-

factor model used by Carhart [1997] (henceforth: “Carhart”); a second pricing model based on the

Daniel, Grinblatt, Titman and Wermers characteristic based benchmarks (“DGTW”); and a third pricing

model based on the 25 Fama-French portfolios sorted on Value and Size (“FF-25”). 19


For the Carhart model, we performed a regression of the fund returns on the four factors of the model

(market, value, size and momentum). The exposure to the four factors resulting from this regression

defined the benchmark of the fund. As a result, the active return of the fund was equal to the alpha of

the fund computed with the Carhart model.

                                                            
19
     See Daniel et al. [1997] and Wermers [2004] for more details on DGTW portfolio. The DGTW benchmarks are available via

http://www.smith.umd.edu/faculty/rwermers/ftpsite/Dgtw/coverpage.htm. The Fama-French portfolio are available via:

http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/data_library.html




September, 2010                                                                                             23
For DGTW, we performed a regression of the fund returns on the market portfolio and one of the 125

characteristic based benchmarks and the market factor. The DGTW benchmarks are the result of a sort

of U.S. stocks on value, size and momentum exposures. We choose a unique DGTW benchmark which,

when combined with the market portfolio, maximizes the variance explained by the regression. The

market portfolio that we used with each of these models was the value-weighted return on all NYSE,

AMEX, and NASDAQ stocks (from CRSP), minus the one-month Treasury bill rate. We followed the same

procedure for the FF-25 portfolios.


For each period we computed the historical active volatility of each asset in each fund using the

securities monthly returns. Asset active volatility is the standard deviation of the difference between

the asset returns and the benchmark returns. If a security does not have at least 24 months of returns,

we set its active volatility to the equal weighted average volatility of the fund’s assets with more than

24 months of returns. Every quarter, we compute the mean weighted volatility. The fund mean

weighted volatility for a period is the mean of each of the quarterly mean weighted volatility during

that period.


For a quarterly observation of the portfolio to be included in our analysis, we required that at least 75%

of the assets in the portfolio be recognized in the CRSP U.S. Stock database. For a fund to be included

in the analysis of a period, we required at least 8 valid quarters. In addition, we excluded from the

analysis, funds that had an average across all quarters of a period more than 5% of assets not

recognized in the CRSP U.S. Stock database. We excluded funds that, on average across all quarters of

a given period, had fewer than 10 positions, or less than 15 million dollars of asset under management.


Using the three models, we computed alpha (active return) and residual risk (active risk) during each of

the periods we analyzed. We then computed the weighted mean asset volatility of each portfolio using

the monthly historical return of each asset in the fund.


Finally, we took the mean of these quarterly volatilities across the entire period to obtain a proxy for

the fund asset weighted volatility (  ) for the period and used the following decomposition to compute

the fund’s skill and diversification.



September, 2010                                                                          24
              
DI=        and SK 
                    

Model Choices


While the Carhart model is the standard pricing model used in the literature, the findings of Cremers

and Petajisto [2009] raised questions about the suitability of this model to establish a pertinent

performance benchmark. Unlike Cremers and Patajisto, we obtained strongly significant results with

the Carhart model. However, we still wanted to ensure that our results were not dependent on the

type of model we were using, so we recomputed our results with two alternative models. The DGTW

benchmarks offer a very granular classification of U.S. stocks into benchmarks based on their value,

size and momentum characteristics. These DGTW benchmarks have fewer stocks than a typical

benchmark and therefore more idiosyncratic risk. We also used a coarser asset classification

framework: the 25 Fama-French value and size sorted portfolios. The disadvantage of the Fama-French

portfolio is that we did not account for the funds’ momentum exposure. Using these three models, we

computed alpha (or active return), residual risk (or active risk), skill and diversification of each

portfolio during each of the periods we analyzed.


In theory, we should also have excluded from the active returns the returns due all non-priced factors

to which the funds are systematically exposed. However, there is an infinite set of non-priced factors

that could be included in the benchmark definition. Therefore, using non-priced factors was not

practical. Since exposures are computed based on the historical co-movement of the fund’s returns and

the factor returns, we would have picked up spurious relations between the funds’ returns and the

factors if we used a larger number of non-priced factors. As a result, we would have obtained a very

narrow definition of the fund’s alpha.




September, 2010                                                                       25

Mais conteúdo relacionado

Mais procurados

[EN] The use of convertible bonds in the asset allocation process
[EN] The use of convertible bonds in the asset allocation process[EN] The use of convertible bonds in the asset allocation process
[EN] The use of convertible bonds in the asset allocation processNN Investment Partners
 
Performance Of Fo F Do Experience And Size Matter
Performance Of Fo F Do Experience And Size MatterPerformance Of Fo F Do Experience And Size Matter
Performance Of Fo F Do Experience And Size Matterchardingsmith
 
Superior performance by combining Rsik Parity with Momentum?
Superior performance by combining Rsik Parity with Momentum?Superior performance by combining Rsik Parity with Momentum?
Superior performance by combining Rsik Parity with Momentum?Wilhelm Fritsche
 
Measurement of Risk and Calculation of Portfolio Risk
Measurement of Risk and Calculation of Portfolio RiskMeasurement of Risk and Calculation of Portfolio Risk
Measurement of Risk and Calculation of Portfolio RiskDhrumil Shah
 
Lodging REIT Analysis - Keynote Presentation for Research Committee by Brad K...
Lodging REIT Analysis - Keynote Presentation for Research Committee by Brad K...Lodging REIT Analysis - Keynote Presentation for Research Committee by Brad K...
Lodging REIT Analysis - Keynote Presentation for Research Committee by Brad K...Brad Kuskin
 
Chapter 08 Risk & Return
Chapter 08 Risk & ReturnChapter 08 Risk & Return
Chapter 08 Risk & ReturnAlamgir Alwani
 
Myth of diversification
Myth of diversificationMyth of diversification
Myth of diversificationbfmresearch
 
HowActuariescanuseFinancialEconomics
HowActuariescanuseFinancialEconomicsHowActuariescanuseFinancialEconomics
HowActuariescanuseFinancialEconomicsAndrew Smith
 
Diversification and portfolio analysis@ bec doms
Diversification and portfolio analysis@ bec domsDiversification and portfolio analysis@ bec doms
Diversification and portfolio analysis@ bec domsBabasab Patil
 
Financial Risk Mgt - Lec 2 by Dr. Syed Muhammad Ali Tirmizi
Financial Risk Mgt - Lec 2 by Dr. Syed Muhammad Ali TirmiziFinancial Risk Mgt - Lec 2 by Dr. Syed Muhammad Ali Tirmizi
Financial Risk Mgt - Lec 2 by Dr. Syed Muhammad Ali TirmiziDr. Muhammad Ali Tirmizi., Ph.D.
 
Active share betteralpha
Active share betteralphaActive share betteralpha
Active share betteralphabfmresearch
 
IAQF report_Cornell Team
IAQF report_Cornell TeamIAQF report_Cornell Team
IAQF report_Cornell TeamJin Li
 
Low Volatility Anomaly Osama Abdetawab
Low Volatility Anomaly Osama AbdetawabLow Volatility Anomaly Osama Abdetawab
Low Volatility Anomaly Osama AbdetawabOsama Elaish
 

Mais procurados (18)

[EN] The use of convertible bonds in the asset allocation process
[EN] The use of convertible bonds in the asset allocation process[EN] The use of convertible bonds in the asset allocation process
[EN] The use of convertible bonds in the asset allocation process
 
Lesson 4
Lesson 4Lesson 4
Lesson 4
 
Performance Of Fo F Do Experience And Size Matter
Performance Of Fo F Do Experience And Size MatterPerformance Of Fo F Do Experience And Size Matter
Performance Of Fo F Do Experience And Size Matter
 
Gy jf final
Gy jf finalGy jf final
Gy jf final
 
Superior performance by combining Rsik Parity with Momentum?
Superior performance by combining Rsik Parity with Momentum?Superior performance by combining Rsik Parity with Momentum?
Superior performance by combining Rsik Parity with Momentum?
 
Measurement of Risk and Calculation of Portfolio Risk
Measurement of Risk and Calculation of Portfolio RiskMeasurement of Risk and Calculation of Portfolio Risk
Measurement of Risk and Calculation of Portfolio Risk
 
Lodging REIT Analysis - Keynote Presentation for Research Committee by Brad K...
Lodging REIT Analysis - Keynote Presentation for Research Committee by Brad K...Lodging REIT Analysis - Keynote Presentation for Research Committee by Brad K...
Lodging REIT Analysis - Keynote Presentation for Research Committee by Brad K...
 
Risk and return
Risk and returnRisk and return
Risk and return
 
Chapter 08 Risk & Return
Chapter 08 Risk & ReturnChapter 08 Risk & Return
Chapter 08 Risk & Return
 
Myth of diversification
Myth of diversificationMyth of diversification
Myth of diversification
 
HowActuariescanuseFinancialEconomics
HowActuariescanuseFinancialEconomicsHowActuariescanuseFinancialEconomics
HowActuariescanuseFinancialEconomics
 
Case real estate
Case real estateCase real estate
Case real estate
 
Diversification and portfolio analysis@ bec doms
Diversification and portfolio analysis@ bec domsDiversification and portfolio analysis@ bec doms
Diversification and portfolio analysis@ bec doms
 
Financial Risk Mgt - Lec 2 by Dr. Syed Muhammad Ali Tirmizi
Financial Risk Mgt - Lec 2 by Dr. Syed Muhammad Ali TirmiziFinancial Risk Mgt - Lec 2 by Dr. Syed Muhammad Ali Tirmizi
Financial Risk Mgt - Lec 2 by Dr. Syed Muhammad Ali Tirmizi
 
Active share betteralpha
Active share betteralphaActive share betteralpha
Active share betteralpha
 
Markowitz model
Markowitz modelMarkowitz model
Markowitz model
 
IAQF report_Cornell Team
IAQF report_Cornell TeamIAQF report_Cornell Team
IAQF report_Cornell Team
 
Low Volatility Anomaly Osama Abdetawab
Low Volatility Anomaly Osama AbdetawabLow Volatility Anomaly Osama Abdetawab
Low Volatility Anomaly Osama Abdetawab
 

Destaque

Measuring luck in estimated alphas barras scaillet
Measuring luck in estimated alphas barras scailletMeasuring luck in estimated alphas barras scaillet
Measuring luck in estimated alphas barras scailletbfmresearch
 
Performance persistence of fixed income funds droms
Performance persistence of fixed income funds dromsPerformance persistence of fixed income funds droms
Performance persistence of fixed income funds dromsbfmresearch
 
Can fundmanagerspickstocks baker
Can fundmanagerspickstocks bakerCan fundmanagerspickstocks baker
Can fundmanagerspickstocks bakerbfmresearch
 
Persistence inmutualfundperformance carhart
Persistence inmutualfundperformance carhartPersistence inmutualfundperformance carhart
Persistence inmutualfundperformance carhartbfmresearch
 
Persistence performance
Persistence performancePersistence performance
Persistence performancebfmresearch
 
12 182-china webcast
12 182-china webcast12 182-china webcast
12 182-china webcastbfmresearch
 
Fis group study on emerging managers performance drivers 2007
Fis group   study on  emerging managers performance drivers 2007Fis group   study on  emerging managers performance drivers 2007
Fis group study on emerging managers performance drivers 2007bfmresearch
 
0large vs small bernstein
0large vs small bernstein0large vs small bernstein
0large vs small bernsteinbfmresearch
 
Predicting returnsfundmanagers stotz
Predicting returnsfundmanagers stotzPredicting returnsfundmanagers stotz
Predicting returnsfundmanagers stotzbfmresearch
 
Short term persistence in mutual fund performance(12)
Short term persistence in mutual fund performance(12)Short term persistence in mutual fund performance(12)
Short term persistence in mutual fund performance(12)bfmresearch
 
Why mutualfundperformancenotpersist misc
Why mutualfundperformancenotpersist miscWhy mutualfundperformancenotpersist misc
Why mutualfundperformancenotpersist miscbfmresearch
 
Prior performance and risk chen and pennacchi
Prior performance and risk chen and pennacchiPrior performance and risk chen and pennacchi
Prior performance and risk chen and pennacchibfmresearch
 
Smart fundmgrsstupidmoney bernhardt
Smart fundmgrsstupidmoney bernhardtSmart fundmgrsstupidmoney bernhardt
Smart fundmgrsstupidmoney bernhardtbfmresearch
 
Bfm newsletter 10_2011
Bfm newsletter 10_2011Bfm newsletter 10_2011
Bfm newsletter 10_2011bfmresearch
 
Cost ofactiveinvesting french
Cost ofactiveinvesting frenchCost ofactiveinvesting french
Cost ofactiveinvesting frenchbfmresearch
 
Performance changes and mgmt turnover khorana
Performance changes and mgmt turnover khoranaPerformance changes and mgmt turnover khorana
Performance changes and mgmt turnover khoranabfmresearch
 
Does skiningamematter cremers
Does skiningamematter cremersDoes skiningamematter cremers
Does skiningamematter cremersbfmresearch
 
Investment beliefsystems nepc
Investment beliefsystems nepcInvestment beliefsystems nepc
Investment beliefsystems nepcbfmresearch
 

Destaque (19)

Measuring luck in estimated alphas barras scaillet
Measuring luck in estimated alphas barras scailletMeasuring luck in estimated alphas barras scaillet
Measuring luck in estimated alphas barras scaillet
 
Performance persistence of fixed income funds droms
Performance persistence of fixed income funds dromsPerformance persistence of fixed income funds droms
Performance persistence of fixed income funds droms
 
Can fundmanagerspickstocks baker
Can fundmanagerspickstocks bakerCan fundmanagerspickstocks baker
Can fundmanagerspickstocks baker
 
Persistence inmutualfundperformance carhart
Persistence inmutualfundperformance carhartPersistence inmutualfundperformance carhart
Persistence inmutualfundperformance carhart
 
Persistence performance
Persistence performancePersistence performance
Persistence performance
 
12 182-china webcast
12 182-china webcast12 182-china webcast
12 182-china webcast
 
Fis group study on emerging managers performance drivers 2007
Fis group   study on  emerging managers performance drivers 2007Fis group   study on  emerging managers performance drivers 2007
Fis group study on emerging managers performance drivers 2007
 
0large vs small bernstein
0large vs small bernstein0large vs small bernstein
0large vs small bernstein
 
Predicting returnsfundmanagers stotz
Predicting returnsfundmanagers stotzPredicting returnsfundmanagers stotz
Predicting returnsfundmanagers stotz
 
Short term persistence in mutual fund performance(12)
Short term persistence in mutual fund performance(12)Short term persistence in mutual fund performance(12)
Short term persistence in mutual fund performance(12)
 
Why mutualfundperformancenotpersist misc
Why mutualfundperformancenotpersist miscWhy mutualfundperformancenotpersist misc
Why mutualfundperformancenotpersist misc
 
Vanguard dc
Vanguard dcVanguard dc
Vanguard dc
 
Prior performance and risk chen and pennacchi
Prior performance and risk chen and pennacchiPrior performance and risk chen and pennacchi
Prior performance and risk chen and pennacchi
 
Smart fundmgrsstupidmoney bernhardt
Smart fundmgrsstupidmoney bernhardtSmart fundmgrsstupidmoney bernhardt
Smart fundmgrsstupidmoney bernhardt
 
Bfm newsletter 10_2011
Bfm newsletter 10_2011Bfm newsletter 10_2011
Bfm newsletter 10_2011
 
Cost ofactiveinvesting french
Cost ofactiveinvesting frenchCost ofactiveinvesting french
Cost ofactiveinvesting french
 
Performance changes and mgmt turnover khorana
Performance changes and mgmt turnover khoranaPerformance changes and mgmt turnover khorana
Performance changes and mgmt turnover khorana
 
Does skiningamematter cremers
Does skiningamematter cremersDoes skiningamematter cremers
Does skiningamematter cremers
 
Investment beliefsystems nepc
Investment beliefsystems nepcInvestment beliefsystems nepc
Investment beliefsystems nepc
 

Semelhante a 2010 09 the empirical law of active management

Thesis final bilal n saif 222 (2010 2011)
Thesis final bilal n saif 222 (2010 2011)Thesis final bilal n saif 222 (2010 2011)
Thesis final bilal n saif 222 (2010 2011)Saifullah Malik
 
Introducing-the-Two-Sigma-Factor-Lens.10.18.pdf
Introducing-the-Two-Sigma-Factor-Lens.10.18.pdfIntroducing-the-Two-Sigma-Factor-Lens.10.18.pdf
Introducing-the-Two-Sigma-Factor-Lens.10.18.pdfClarenceTee1
 
The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punish...
The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punish...The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punish...
The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punish...RyanMHolcomb
 
EffectivePortfolioDimensionality_StandardLifeInvestments.PDF
EffectivePortfolioDimensionality_StandardLifeInvestments.PDFEffectivePortfolioDimensionality_StandardLifeInvestments.PDF
EffectivePortfolioDimensionality_StandardLifeInvestments.PDFBrian Fleming
 
Information ratio mgrevaluation_bossert
Information ratio mgrevaluation_bossertInformation ratio mgrevaluation_bossert
Information ratio mgrevaluation_bossertbfmresearch
 
Risk Factors as Building Blocks for Portfolio Diversification
Risk Factors as Building Blocks for Portfolio DiversificationRisk Factors as Building Blocks for Portfolio Diversification
Risk Factors as Building Blocks for Portfolio DiversificationCallan
 
Mercer Capital | Valuation Insight | Corporate Finance in 30 Minutes
Mercer Capital | Valuation Insight | Corporate Finance in 30 Minutes Mercer Capital | Valuation Insight | Corporate Finance in 30 Minutes
Mercer Capital | Valuation Insight | Corporate Finance in 30 Minutes Mercer Capital
 
TO STUDY THE OPTIMIZATION OF PORTFOLIO RISK AND RETURN
TO STUDY THE OPTIMIZATION OF PORTFOLIO RISK AND RETURNTO STUDY THE OPTIMIZATION OF PORTFOLIO RISK AND RETURN
TO STUDY THE OPTIMIZATION OF PORTFOLIO RISK AND RETURNPriyansh Kesarwani
 
Exploring Index Effects - Tamas Toth
Exploring Index Effects - Tamas TothExploring Index Effects - Tamas Toth
Exploring Index Effects - Tamas TothTamas Toth, CFA
 
Investing intalents li_zhang
Investing intalents li_zhangInvesting intalents li_zhang
Investing intalents li_zhangbfmresearch
 
Determinants of capital structure
Determinants of capital structureDeterminants of capital structure
Determinants of capital structureFarooq Jamal
 
Ownership and fund performance evans
Ownership and fund performance evansOwnership and fund performance evans
Ownership and fund performance evansbfmresearch
 
Mercer Capital - Corporate Finance in 30 Minutes Whitepaper.pdf
Mercer Capital - Corporate Finance in 30 Minutes Whitepaper.pdfMercer Capital - Corporate Finance in 30 Minutes Whitepaper.pdf
Mercer Capital - Corporate Finance in 30 Minutes Whitepaper.pdfMercer Capital
 
AIAR Winter 2015 - Henry Ma Adaptive Invest Approach
AIAR Winter 2015 - Henry Ma Adaptive Invest ApproachAIAR Winter 2015 - Henry Ma Adaptive Invest Approach
AIAR Winter 2015 - Henry Ma Adaptive Invest ApproachHenry Ma
 
Collateralized Fund Obligations MSc thesis Executive Summary
Collateralized Fund Obligations MSc thesis Executive SummaryCollateralized Fund Obligations MSc thesis Executive Summary
Collateralized Fund Obligations MSc thesis Executive SummaryNICOLA Padovani
 

Semelhante a 2010 09 the empirical law of active management (20)

Thesis final bilal n saif 222 (2010 2011)
Thesis final bilal n saif 222 (2010 2011)Thesis final bilal n saif 222 (2010 2011)
Thesis final bilal n saif 222 (2010 2011)
 
Introducing-the-Two-Sigma-Factor-Lens.10.18.pdf
Introducing-the-Two-Sigma-Factor-Lens.10.18.pdfIntroducing-the-Two-Sigma-Factor-Lens.10.18.pdf
Introducing-the-Two-Sigma-Factor-Lens.10.18.pdf
 
The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punish...
The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punish...The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punish...
The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punish...
 
EffectivePortfolioDimensionality_StandardLifeInvestments.PDF
EffectivePortfolioDimensionality_StandardLifeInvestments.PDFEffectivePortfolioDimensionality_StandardLifeInvestments.PDF
EffectivePortfolioDimensionality_StandardLifeInvestments.PDF
 
Information ratio mgrevaluation_bossert
Information ratio mgrevaluation_bossertInformation ratio mgrevaluation_bossert
Information ratio mgrevaluation_bossert
 
Risk Factors as Building Blocks for Portfolio Diversification
Risk Factors as Building Blocks for Portfolio DiversificationRisk Factors as Building Blocks for Portfolio Diversification
Risk Factors as Building Blocks for Portfolio Diversification
 
Mercer Capital | Valuation Insight | Corporate Finance in 30 Minutes
Mercer Capital | Valuation Insight | Corporate Finance in 30 Minutes Mercer Capital | Valuation Insight | Corporate Finance in 30 Minutes
Mercer Capital | Valuation Insight | Corporate Finance in 30 Minutes
 
Hedge funds
Hedge fundsHedge funds
Hedge funds
 
TO STUDY THE OPTIMIZATION OF PORTFOLIO RISK AND RETURN
TO STUDY THE OPTIMIZATION OF PORTFOLIO RISK AND RETURNTO STUDY THE OPTIMIZATION OF PORTFOLIO RISK AND RETURN
TO STUDY THE OPTIMIZATION OF PORTFOLIO RISK AND RETURN
 
Exploring Index Effects - Tamas Toth
Exploring Index Effects - Tamas TothExploring Index Effects - Tamas Toth
Exploring Index Effects - Tamas Toth
 
Ssrn id1685942
Ssrn id1685942Ssrn id1685942
Ssrn id1685942
 
Ssrn id1685942
Ssrn id1685942Ssrn id1685942
Ssrn id1685942
 
Investing intalents li_zhang
Investing intalents li_zhangInvesting intalents li_zhang
Investing intalents li_zhang
 
Determinants of capital structure
Determinants of capital structureDeterminants of capital structure
Determinants of capital structure
 
Ownership and fund performance evans
Ownership and fund performance evansOwnership and fund performance evans
Ownership and fund performance evans
 
Mercer Capital - Corporate Finance in 30 Minutes Whitepaper.pdf
Mercer Capital - Corporate Finance in 30 Minutes Whitepaper.pdfMercer Capital - Corporate Finance in 30 Minutes Whitepaper.pdf
Mercer Capital - Corporate Finance in 30 Minutes Whitepaper.pdf
 
Edhec Working Paper Solvency II
Edhec Working Paper Solvency IIEdhec Working Paper Solvency II
Edhec Working Paper Solvency II
 
Mb2521002105
Mb2521002105Mb2521002105
Mb2521002105
 
AIAR Winter 2015 - Henry Ma Adaptive Invest Approach
AIAR Winter 2015 - Henry Ma Adaptive Invest ApproachAIAR Winter 2015 - Henry Ma Adaptive Invest Approach
AIAR Winter 2015 - Henry Ma Adaptive Invest Approach
 
Collateralized Fund Obligations MSc thesis Executive Summary
Collateralized Fund Obligations MSc thesis Executive SummaryCollateralized Fund Obligations MSc thesis Executive Summary
Collateralized Fund Obligations MSc thesis Executive Summary
 

Mais de bfmresearch

Impact ofmutualfundclosuresonfundmanagers
Impact ofmutualfundclosuresonfundmanagersImpact ofmutualfundclosuresonfundmanagers
Impact ofmutualfundclosuresonfundmanagersbfmresearch
 
Standard & poor's 16768282 fund-factors-2009 jan1
Standard & poor's 16768282 fund-factors-2009 jan1Standard & poor's 16768282 fund-factors-2009 jan1
Standard & poor's 16768282 fund-factors-2009 jan1bfmresearch
 
Performance emergingfixedincomemanagers joi_is age just a number
Performance emergingfixedincomemanagers joi_is age just a numberPerformance emergingfixedincomemanagers joi_is age just a number
Performance emergingfixedincomemanagers joi_is age just a numberbfmresearch
 
Portfolio turnover white paper
Portfolio turnover white paperPortfolio turnover white paper
Portfolio turnover white paperbfmresearch
 
Mauboussin skill manager
Mauboussin skill managerMauboussin skill manager
Mauboussin skill managerbfmresearch
 
Is alphadead researchnote
Is alphadead researchnoteIs alphadead researchnote
Is alphadead researchnotebfmresearch
 
Barclays manager selection0312
Barclays   manager selection0312Barclays   manager selection0312
Barclays manager selection0312bfmresearch
 
Active managementmostlyefficientmarkets faj
Active managementmostlyefficientmarkets fajActive managementmostlyefficientmarkets faj
Active managementmostlyefficientmarkets fajbfmresearch
 
2012 0224 active share
2012 0224 active share2012 0224 active share
2012 0224 active sharebfmresearch
 
Scoring For Returns-Stuart Investment
Scoring For Returns-Stuart InvestmentScoring For Returns-Stuart Investment
Scoring For Returns-Stuart Investmentbfmresearch
 
Performance teammgmtvsindividual bliss
Performance teammgmtvsindividual blissPerformance teammgmtvsindividual bliss
Performance teammgmtvsindividual blissbfmresearch
 
Returns basedstyleanalysisinexcel mcdermott
Returns basedstyleanalysisinexcel mcdermottReturns basedstyleanalysisinexcel mcdermott
Returns basedstyleanalysisinexcel mcdermottbfmresearch
 
Fund size, liquidity and org chen hong
Fund size, liquidity and org chen hongFund size, liquidity and org chen hong
Fund size, liquidity and org chen hongbfmresearch
 
Examination of hedged mutual funds agarwal
Examination of hedged mutual funds agarwalExamination of hedged mutual funds agarwal
Examination of hedged mutual funds agarwalbfmresearch
 
Morningstar ratings and fund performance blake morey
Morningstar ratings and fund performance blake moreyMorningstar ratings and fund performance blake morey
Morningstar ratings and fund performance blake moreybfmresearch
 
Fund returnsandperformanceevaluationtechniques grinblatt
Fund returnsandperformanceevaluationtechniques grinblattFund returnsandperformanceevaluationtechniques grinblatt
Fund returnsandperformanceevaluationtechniques grinblattbfmresearch
 
Momentum investingperformanceandherding grinblatt
Momentum investingperformanceandherding grinblattMomentum investingperformanceandherding grinblatt
Momentum investingperformanceandherding grinblattbfmresearch
 
Performance of trades and stocks of fund managers pinnuck
Performance of trades and stocks of fund managers pinnuckPerformance of trades and stocks of fund managers pinnuck
Performance of trades and stocks of fund managers pinnuckbfmresearch
 

Mais de bfmresearch (20)

Impact ofmutualfundclosuresonfundmanagers
Impact ofmutualfundclosuresonfundmanagersImpact ofmutualfundclosuresonfundmanagers
Impact ofmutualfundclosuresonfundmanagers
 
Standard & poor's 16768282 fund-factors-2009 jan1
Standard & poor's 16768282 fund-factors-2009 jan1Standard & poor's 16768282 fund-factors-2009 jan1
Standard & poor's 16768282 fund-factors-2009 jan1
 
Performance emergingfixedincomemanagers joi_is age just a number
Performance emergingfixedincomemanagers joi_is age just a numberPerformance emergingfixedincomemanagers joi_is age just a number
Performance emergingfixedincomemanagers joi_is age just a number
 
Spiva mid2011
Spiva mid2011Spiva mid2011
Spiva mid2011
 
Portfolio turnover white paper
Portfolio turnover white paperPortfolio turnover white paper
Portfolio turnover white paper
 
Mauboussin skill manager
Mauboussin skill managerMauboussin skill manager
Mauboussin skill manager
 
Jp littlebook
Jp littlebookJp littlebook
Jp littlebook
 
Is alphadead researchnote
Is alphadead researchnoteIs alphadead researchnote
Is alphadead researchnote
 
Barclays manager selection0312
Barclays   manager selection0312Barclays   manager selection0312
Barclays manager selection0312
 
Active managementmostlyefficientmarkets faj
Active managementmostlyefficientmarkets fajActive managementmostlyefficientmarkets faj
Active managementmostlyefficientmarkets faj
 
2012 0224 active share
2012 0224 active share2012 0224 active share
2012 0224 active share
 
Scoring For Returns-Stuart Investment
Scoring For Returns-Stuart InvestmentScoring For Returns-Stuart Investment
Scoring For Returns-Stuart Investment
 
Performance teammgmtvsindividual bliss
Performance teammgmtvsindividual blissPerformance teammgmtvsindividual bliss
Performance teammgmtvsindividual bliss
 
Returns basedstyleanalysisinexcel mcdermott
Returns basedstyleanalysisinexcel mcdermottReturns basedstyleanalysisinexcel mcdermott
Returns basedstyleanalysisinexcel mcdermott
 
Fund size, liquidity and org chen hong
Fund size, liquidity and org chen hongFund size, liquidity and org chen hong
Fund size, liquidity and org chen hong
 
Examination of hedged mutual funds agarwal
Examination of hedged mutual funds agarwalExamination of hedged mutual funds agarwal
Examination of hedged mutual funds agarwal
 
Morningstar ratings and fund performance blake morey
Morningstar ratings and fund performance blake moreyMorningstar ratings and fund performance blake morey
Morningstar ratings and fund performance blake morey
 
Fund returnsandperformanceevaluationtechniques grinblatt
Fund returnsandperformanceevaluationtechniques grinblattFund returnsandperformanceevaluationtechniques grinblatt
Fund returnsandperformanceevaluationtechniques grinblatt
 
Momentum investingperformanceandherding grinblatt
Momentum investingperformanceandherding grinblattMomentum investingperformanceandherding grinblatt
Momentum investingperformanceandherding grinblatt
 
Performance of trades and stocks of fund managers pinnuck
Performance of trades and stocks of fund managers pinnuckPerformance of trades and stocks of fund managers pinnuck
Performance of trades and stocks of fund managers pinnuck
 

Último

Instant Issue Debit Cards - High School Spirit
Instant Issue Debit Cards - High School SpiritInstant Issue Debit Cards - High School Spirit
Instant Issue Debit Cards - High School Spiritegoetzinger
 
05_Annelore Lenoir_Docbyte_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pptx
05_Annelore Lenoir_Docbyte_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pptx05_Annelore Lenoir_Docbyte_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pptx
05_Annelore Lenoir_Docbyte_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pptxFinTech Belgium
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 22.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 22.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 22.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 22.pdfGale Pooley
 
Stock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdfStock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdfMichael Silva
 
High Class Call Girls Nashik Maya 7001305949 Independent Escort Service Nashik
High Class Call Girls Nashik Maya 7001305949 Independent Escort Service NashikHigh Class Call Girls Nashik Maya 7001305949 Independent Escort Service Nashik
High Class Call Girls Nashik Maya 7001305949 Independent Escort Service NashikCall Girls in Nagpur High Profile
 
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130Suhani Kapoor
 
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur EscortsCall Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escortsranjana rawat
 
VVIP Pune Call Girls Katraj (7001035870) Pune Escorts Nearby with Complete Sa...
VVIP Pune Call Girls Katraj (7001035870) Pune Escorts Nearby with Complete Sa...VVIP Pune Call Girls Katraj (7001035870) Pune Escorts Nearby with Complete Sa...
VVIP Pune Call Girls Katraj (7001035870) Pune Escorts Nearby with Complete Sa...Call Girls in Nagpur High Profile
 
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Talegaon Dabhade 6297143586 Call Hot ...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Talegaon Dabhade  6297143586 Call Hot ...Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Talegaon Dabhade  6297143586 Call Hot ...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Talegaon Dabhade 6297143586 Call Hot ...Call Girls in Nagpur High Profile
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdfGale Pooley
 
Call US 📞 9892124323 ✅ Kurla Call Girls In Kurla ( Mumbai ) secure service
Call US 📞 9892124323 ✅ Kurla Call Girls In Kurla ( Mumbai ) secure serviceCall US 📞 9892124323 ✅ Kurla Call Girls In Kurla ( Mumbai ) secure service
Call US 📞 9892124323 ✅ Kurla Call Girls In Kurla ( Mumbai ) secure servicePooja Nehwal
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 20.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 20.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 20.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 20.pdfGale Pooley
 
(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...ranjana rawat
 
Vip Call US 📞 7738631006 ✅Call Girls In Sakinaka ( Mumbai )
Vip Call US 📞 7738631006 ✅Call Girls In Sakinaka ( Mumbai )Vip Call US 📞 7738631006 ✅Call Girls In Sakinaka ( Mumbai )
Vip Call US 📞 7738631006 ✅Call Girls In Sakinaka ( Mumbai )Pooja Nehwal
 
Log your LOA pain with Pension Lab's brilliant campaign
Log your LOA pain with Pension Lab's brilliant campaignLog your LOA pain with Pension Lab's brilliant campaign
Log your LOA pain with Pension Lab's brilliant campaignHenry Tapper
 
VIP Call Girls LB Nagar ( Hyderabad ) Phone 8250192130 | ₹5k To 25k With Room...
VIP Call Girls LB Nagar ( Hyderabad ) Phone 8250192130 | ₹5k To 25k With Room...VIP Call Girls LB Nagar ( Hyderabad ) Phone 8250192130 | ₹5k To 25k With Room...
VIP Call Girls LB Nagar ( Hyderabad ) Phone 8250192130 | ₹5k To 25k With Room...Suhani Kapoor
 
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Viman Nagar ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex...
Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Viman Nagar ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex...Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Viman Nagar ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex...
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Viman Nagar ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex...Call Girls in Nagpur High Profile
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 25.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 25.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 25.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 25.pdfGale Pooley
 

Último (20)

Instant Issue Debit Cards - High School Spirit
Instant Issue Debit Cards - High School SpiritInstant Issue Debit Cards - High School Spirit
Instant Issue Debit Cards - High School Spirit
 
05_Annelore Lenoir_Docbyte_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pptx
05_Annelore Lenoir_Docbyte_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pptx05_Annelore Lenoir_Docbyte_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pptx
05_Annelore Lenoir_Docbyte_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pptx
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 22.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 22.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 22.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 22.pdf
 
Stock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdfStock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdf
 
High Class Call Girls Nashik Maya 7001305949 Independent Escort Service Nashik
High Class Call Girls Nashik Maya 7001305949 Independent Escort Service NashikHigh Class Call Girls Nashik Maya 7001305949 Independent Escort Service Nashik
High Class Call Girls Nashik Maya 7001305949 Independent Escort Service Nashik
 
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
 
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur EscortsCall Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
 
Veritas Interim Report 1 January–31 March 2024
Veritas Interim Report 1 January–31 March 2024Veritas Interim Report 1 January–31 March 2024
Veritas Interim Report 1 January–31 March 2024
 
VVIP Pune Call Girls Katraj (7001035870) Pune Escorts Nearby with Complete Sa...
VVIP Pune Call Girls Katraj (7001035870) Pune Escorts Nearby with Complete Sa...VVIP Pune Call Girls Katraj (7001035870) Pune Escorts Nearby with Complete Sa...
VVIP Pune Call Girls Katraj (7001035870) Pune Escorts Nearby with Complete Sa...
 
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Talegaon Dabhade 6297143586 Call Hot ...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Talegaon Dabhade  6297143586 Call Hot ...Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Talegaon Dabhade  6297143586 Call Hot ...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Talegaon Dabhade 6297143586 Call Hot ...
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdf
 
Call US 📞 9892124323 ✅ Kurla Call Girls In Kurla ( Mumbai ) secure service
Call US 📞 9892124323 ✅ Kurla Call Girls In Kurla ( Mumbai ) secure serviceCall US 📞 9892124323 ✅ Kurla Call Girls In Kurla ( Mumbai ) secure service
Call US 📞 9892124323 ✅ Kurla Call Girls In Kurla ( Mumbai ) secure service
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 20.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 20.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 20.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 20.pdf
 
Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - April 2024
Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - April 2024Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - April 2024
Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - April 2024
 
(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
 
Vip Call US 📞 7738631006 ✅Call Girls In Sakinaka ( Mumbai )
Vip Call US 📞 7738631006 ✅Call Girls In Sakinaka ( Mumbai )Vip Call US 📞 7738631006 ✅Call Girls In Sakinaka ( Mumbai )
Vip Call US 📞 7738631006 ✅Call Girls In Sakinaka ( Mumbai )
 
Log your LOA pain with Pension Lab's brilliant campaign
Log your LOA pain with Pension Lab's brilliant campaignLog your LOA pain with Pension Lab's brilliant campaign
Log your LOA pain with Pension Lab's brilliant campaign
 
VIP Call Girls LB Nagar ( Hyderabad ) Phone 8250192130 | ₹5k To 25k With Room...
VIP Call Girls LB Nagar ( Hyderabad ) Phone 8250192130 | ₹5k To 25k With Room...VIP Call Girls LB Nagar ( Hyderabad ) Phone 8250192130 | ₹5k To 25k With Room...
VIP Call Girls LB Nagar ( Hyderabad ) Phone 8250192130 | ₹5k To 25k With Room...
 
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Viman Nagar ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex...
Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Viman Nagar ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex...Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Viman Nagar ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex...
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Viman Nagar ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex...
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 25.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 25.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 25.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 25.pdf
 

2010 09 the empirical law of active management

  • 1. The Empirical Law of Active Management Perspectives on the Declining Skill of U.S. Fund Managers Edouard Senechal, CFA Forthcoming Journal of Portfolio Management Fall 2010 Abstract: This paper proposes a new analytical framework for assessing the breadth (or diversification) and skill of a portfolio manager: the Empirical Law of Active Management. This framework requires no assumption regarding the manager’s asset returns expectations or investment process. It generalizes Grinold’s [1989] Fundamental Law of Active Management, and creates an analytical framework for measuring skill and diversification in a consistent manner for large cross sections of funds. We applied this framework to analyze the evolution of skill and diversification since 1980 for 2,798 U.S. mutual funds and found that skill has been declining among U.S. mutual funds while diversification has been increasing. We put forward two explanations for this decrease in skill. First, the growth in mutual fund assets has made it more difficult for the industry as a whole to outperform the market. Second, our analysis of the relationship between skill and diversification led us to conclude that the U.S. mutual fund industry responded to an increase in the demand for its products by creating funds with less information content. This is the submitted version of the following article: “The Empirical Law of Active Management; Perspectives on the Declining Skill of U.S. Fund Managers”, Edouard Sénéchal, Journal of Portfolio Management, Fall 2010, Copyright © 2010, Institutional Investor, Inc. which will be published in its final form at: http://www.iijournals.com/toc/jpm/current The author would like to thank Brian Singer for his encouragements, inputs and constructive critics, Russell Wermers for helpful suggestions, Eugene Fama and the participants at the spring 2009 “Research Project: Finance” course at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business, Edwin Denson, Greg Fedorinchick and Mabel Lung for helpful suggestions. September, 2010 1
  • 2. The Fundamental Law of Active Management says that the information ratio of a portfolio is the product of the skill of the manager in selecting securities and the breadth of the strategy. In this construct, “skill” is measured by the correlation between the manager’s expected and realized returns, and “breadth” is the square-root of the number of independent positions in the portfolio. Grinold and Kahn [1999] state: “The Fundamental Law is designed to give us insight into active management. It isn’t an operational tool.” nevertheless, the usefulness of these insights has led practitioners to seek to make it an operational tool. The main advance in this direction were brought by Clarke, de Silva and Thorley [2002], who introduced the concept of transfer coefficient1 to account for the constraints that a manager faces when implementing a particular strategy. They also worked out the application of the Fundamental Law to ex-post performance attribution. However, despite these advances, the practical application of the Fundamental Law of Active Management remains difficult. Firstly, one needs to have access to the manager’s return expectations, which are hard to obtain. For qualitatively-oriented managers, return expectations are not formalized in a way that allows the 2 computation of an information coefficient. Often quantitative managers will not make this information available to external investors in order to avoid potential reverse engineering of the manager’s investment process. Moreover, when assessing a manager, using information that can be independently verified is always preferable. Secondly, the Fundamental Law relies heavily on the assumption that managers follow the precepts of the active portfolio management theory developed in Grinold and Kahn [1999]. Hence, applications of the Fundamental Law to managers that do not follow these precepts will lead to questionable results. Finally, by seeking to transform the Fundamental Law into an operational tool, researchers have also made it more complex and difficult to interpret (See Clarke, de Silva and Thorley [2006] or Buckle [2004]). One of the key advantages of the analytical framework proposed in this paper is the simplicity                                                              1 The transfer coefficient is the correlation between optimal unconstrained portfolio weights and actual portfolio weights 2 The information coefficient is the correlation between the manager expected returns and realized returns  September, 2010 2
  • 3. of its application. This approach only requires portfolio holdings and realized returns to analyze how the breadth of the portfolio and the skill of a manager contribute to the information ratio of the portfolio. It does not require any information regarding the manager’s expected returns or assumptions with respect to the manager’s investment process. A New Approach to Estimating Breadth: The Diversification Factor The fact that the Fundamental Law is difficult to apply to many portfolios does not mean that it does not apply. Indeed, the risk adjusted returns of a portfolio, no matter what the investment process is, will always be a function of a manager’s skill and a strategy’s breadth. In order to apply the Fundamental Law to a wider range of strategies, we sidestep the issues outlined in the introduction by starting from portfolio weights rather than the manager’s expected alphas. The cornerstone of this approach consists of computing what would be the information ratio (IR) of the portfolio if there were no diversification benefits (i.e. if all positions in the portfolio were perfectly correlated). The difference between the IR computed assuming that all positions are perfectly correlated and the actual IR represents the benefits from diversification. On the other hand, the IR of the portfolio in the absence of diversification benefits represents the skill of the manager. If there were no benefit from portfolio diversification, the active risk of the portfolio would be the position-weighted mean active volatility of the assets included in the portfolio3:    wi i i Where wi is the weight of asset i and  i is the active volatility of asset i. The asset active volatility is defined as the volatility of the return difference between the benchmark and the asset. Hence the impact of diversification on the active risk of the portfolio can be measured by the ratio of the position-weighted mean volatility (  ) and the actual portfolio active risk(  ). The higher the                                                                3 See appendix 1 for proof September, 2010 3
  • 4. ratio is, the larger the impact of diversification. Hence, we define the diversification factor (DI) as follows:  DI=  As a result, the active risk of a portfolio can be written as:   DI There are three elements that will affect the diversification of the portfolio: the number of positions, the correlation between these positions and the concentration of assets’ weights and assets’ volatilities. The first element is fairly straightforward. More positions mean more diversification. However, not all positions bring the same level of diversification. Adding highly correlated positions to the portfolio creates little diversification. Hence, the second element that impacts the diversification of the portfolio is the level of correlation among the positions in the portfolio. The concentration of the weights in the portfolio will also impact the diversification factor. Indeed, if we consider a portfolio where one position’s weight is 20 times the weight of all the other positions, the diversification of this portfolio will be lower than that of a similar portfolio where all positions are equally weighted. The same logic applies to volatilities. If one asset’s volatility is 20 times that of the other assets, the portfolio return will be highly dependent on the outcome of this one bet and its diversification will be lower than if all volatilities were equal. Concentration of positions’ weights and concentration of positions’ volatilities have the same impact on diversification. They both reduce it by making the portfolio more dependent on fewer positions. We regroup these two variables into one variable, the concentration of the risk-weights (where risk-weights for position i is equal to ( wi i )  ). We show in appendix 1 that the portfolio diversification can be written as a function of these three factors: DI= 1 (Equation 1) 1    n  (i ) n September, 2010 4
  • 5. Where:  n is the number of positions in the portfolio   is roughly a risk-weighted average correlation among the positions in the portfolios4  i is the risk-weight of position i, (i.e. i  (wi i )  )   (i ) is the standard deviation of the risk weights across the portfolio, measuring the concentration in the portfolio. The diversification factor can be interpreted as a number of positions. Let’s illustrate this point with the example of a portfolio that contains ten positions, where the active returns of these positions are independent and each position has an equal risk-weight of 10%. In this example,  =  ( ) =0 and therefore it follows from equation (1) that the diversification of the portfolio is 10. Hence, for any portfolio, diversification represents the equivalent number of independent positions with equal risk- weights. A New Approach to Estimating Skill To assess the impact of diversification on the risk-adjusted returns of a portfolio, we need to divide the numerator and the denominator of the information ration by  :     IR   *  DI      Where  is the active return of the portfolio. Then we define the quantity as the skill (SK) of the  manager which yields: IR  SK * DI                                                              4 see exact formula in appendix 1  September, 2010 5
  • 6. The Empirical Law of Active Management expresses exactly the same fact as the Fundamental Law, namely, that IR is a product of skill and diversification. However, using the Empirical Law, we do not need to make any assumptions about the way in which the portfolio is constructed. The only information that is required to analyze the skill and diversification of the manager is a portfolio’s holdings and realized returns. Skill in the context of the Empirical Law represents the ability of the manager to allocate its risk- capital to securities with high risk-adjusted returns. To demonstrate this point, we need to observe that the portfolio alpha is also the weighted average alpha of each security in the portfolio (i.e.    wi i ). Then we can express skill as the risk-weighted average of the information ratios of the i individual positions in the portfolio: i   w  i i SK   i i   i IRi   i Where IRi is the information ratio of position i and i its risk-weight. In this framework, skill represents the ability of the manager to select securities that have a strong information ratio on a stand-alone basis. In other words, it is a measure of the manager’s ability to maximize the risk- adjusted returns of the portfolio without using the benefit of risk diversification. It is important to note that in the Empirical Law, the skill coefficient is defined more broadly than the information coefficient of the Fundamental Law. Whereas the information coefficient measures the pure stock picking ability of the manager, the skill factor, in addition to stock picking, also incorporates the impact of portfolio concentration and the size of the manager’s opportunity. We can illustrate this point by examining the covariance between the risk-weights and the information ratio:5  ~ ~ 1 n i  ~ ~ 1 n i ~ 1  Cov  , IR  ~  i * IRi  ~  i  * ~  IRi n i ~                                                                 5 Note that this decomposition was inspired by Andrew Lo’s AP decomposition. See proposition 1 in Lo [2007] September, 2010 6
  • 7. ~ ~ Where i and IRi are the risk weights and information ratios of each of the securities in the manager’s investment universe and ~ n is the number of securities in the investment universe. We define investment universe as the entire set of securities in which the manager can invest. (The ~ denotes that the variable covers the entire universe as opposed to securities included in the portfolio only.) By including all the securities in the manager’s universe in our covariance computation, we can fully capture the relation between risk-weights and information ratios. Indeed, securities that are in the manager universe but not in the portfolio do not directly contribute to the risk adjusted return of the portfolio; however, they do contain information with respect to the manager’s stock-picking skill.  IR   0 . ~ Given that the universe is a passive and information-less portfolio, we can assume that i i   * IR is our skill factor. ~ ~ The expectation of the risk-weights and information ratio products: i i i Hence, we can re-write the skill of the manager in function of the covariance between securities risk weights and information ratios: ~ ~ ~ SK  n Cov( , IR  ~ ~ Finally, if n is large enough so that   IR )  1, we obtain: ~ ~ ~ ~ SK   ( , IR n   ) This decomposition of the skill factor is helpful to understand the three elements that are important in determining the skill of a manager: ~ ~   ( , IR  : The correlation between risk-weights and securities information ratios is similar to the information coefficient in the Fundamental Law; it represents the ability of the manager to pick-securities.  ~ n : The size of the universe of securities that the manager will analyze. It represents the opportunity set from which the manager can create value added for his clients.  ~   ) : A measure of the portfolio concentration. This parameter illustrates the fact that a more concentrated portfolio will better leverage the manager’s stock picking ability. September, 2010 7
  • 8. This last point illustrates the fact that diversification also forces managers to go down the list of their investment ideas and implement positions with less expected return. Comparison of the Fundamental and Empirical Laws The Empirical Law and Fundamental Law possess two key differences. First, the Empirical Law side steps the concepts of information coefficient and transfer coefficient. The skill of a manager depends on the relation between risk-weight and risk-adjusted performance (see Exhibit 1). As we discussed in the introduction, for manager-of-managers, the information necessary to compute a transfer coefficient or information coefficient is not available. In practice, fundamental managers cannot cleanly separate transfer coefficient and breadth. The concept of TC makes sense for quantitative managers using models that provide expected returns on wide ranges of securities irrespective of whether they can be implemented or not. On the other hand, given the cost of bottom-up research, fundamental analysts focus on trades that can be implemented. In an investment firm that runs long only portfolios, one rarely sees analysts spending much time on overvalued assets. This makes the distinction between transfer coefficient and diversification less meaningful for fundamental managers. Exhibit 1: Information Triangle Fundamental Law Empirical Law Manager Proprietary Information Ex‐ante Alphas Information  Transfer  Coefficient Coefficient Performance SK  Portfolio  Positions (or Risk –Weights) Public Information for Traditional Funds This diagram is inspired from Figure 1 of Clarke de Silva Thorley (2002). September, 2010 8
  • 9. Therefore, the Empirical Law does not distinguish between the two. If a position is not in the portfolio, we do not seek to know if this is due to lack of breadth or poor transfer coefficient. However, given access to the unconstrained optimal weights of a quantitative manager, we have the flexibility to reintroduce the concept of transfer coefficient. By recomputing the manager IR, DI and SK with these optimal weights (noted IR*, DI* and SK*), we can define our transfer coefficient as:6 IR TC  , which yields IR  TC * SK * DI * * * IR The second key difference between the two approaches is that the Fundamental Law makes the assumption that the portfolio manager uses a mean variance optimization to construct the portfolio. The Empirical Law does not rely on any formal assumption regarding the manager’s portfolio construction process, and uses the fund’s IR as the yardstick of a manager’s success. Can you get indigestion from the diversification free lunch? Warren Buffett has observed that “Diversification is a protection against ignorance. It makes very little sense for those who know what they're doing.”7 Indeed, diversification forces the skilled manager to reduce the portfolio’s concentration in the positions with the highest expected return in order to reduce risk. If one has perfect foresight there is no risk, and there is little to be gained in reducing risk through diversification. However, for investment managers with less than perfect foresight diversification makes a lot of sense. As we noted previously, while diversification also forces portfolio managers to add to the portfolio positions with decreasing risk-adjusted return. Moreover, bottom-up stock picking requires specialized knowledge in the securities being analyzed. Thus far, we have implicitly assumed that skill is a fixed quantity that is inherent to the investment process and can be leveraged into as many trades as one can implement. While this somewhat reflects                                                              6 Note than in theory this TC can be greater than one. Since the objective function that produces the optimal weights of the manager is not necessarily the IR, it is conceivable that the constrained IR be greater than the unconstrained IR. 7 Source: http://en.wikiquote.org/wiki/Warren_Buffett   September, 2010 9
  • 10. the way quantitative managers create value, for fundamental managers more diversification means less depth of research. Therefore, a fixed SK coefficient does not reflect the tradeoff between quality of coverage (or depth) and breadth of coverage, which fundamental managers do face. Fundamental managers could leverage their SK factor across other trades only if they hire more analysts of the same quality; however, producing a good analyst is costly and/or time-consuming. In the long term, it is feasible to grow a research team, but there are usually increased inefficiencies that come with larger organizations.8 Concentration also has negative consequences for risk adjusted returns. The most obvious disadvantage of concentration is that it will result in a higher risk. Hence, the optimal balance between diversification and skill also depends on the client ability to take risk and to diversify this risk. For institutional investors with long investment horizons and the resources to effectively detect skillful managers, diversification is relatively cheap to obtain. In theory, such investors should seek concentrated portfolios where skill is not diluted by diversification. For retail investors who have to support higher transaction costs and cannot perform extensive due diligence, investing in few diversified portfolios makes more sense. For a given fund size, more concentration will automatically result in less liquid positions, which, everything else being equal, will have a negative impact on performance.9 Empirical Analysis of the Relation between Diversification and Skill Two empirical studies have found that mutual funds with high levels of concentration tend to outperform funds with lower levels of concentration. Kacperczyk et al.[2005, 2007] found that small-                                                              8 Chen et al. [2004], find results consistent with this view. They observe that small sized funds outperform large sized funds and argue that part of this difference in performance is due to organizational diseconomies related to hierarchy costs. 9 See Becker and Vaughan [2001] for illustration of this point, see also Chen et al. [2004] who find that a key variable to explain difference in performance between small funds and large funds is liquidity.  September, 2010 10
  • 11. cap funds with higher levels of industry concentration were generating greater alpha than funds with lower levels of industry concentration. Cremers and Petajisto [2008] measured the fund concentration with its active share and found that funds with high concentration outperformed funds with low concentration. The measures of concentration used in these two studies focus on the concentration of portfolio weights. Unlike the DI coefficient these measures of concentration do not capture the impact 10 of concentration in positions’ volatilities and correlations among positions. In order to understand the relation between portfolio diversification and skill, we applied the Empirical Law of Active Management to a universe of 2,798 U.S. mutual funds invested in domestic equities from 1980 to 2006. The first obstacle we faced in assessing the skill of a manager was defining the benchmark. While the concept of benchmark is ubiquitous in today’s asset management industry, it was not the case in the 80’s and early 90’s. Hence, finding an accurate and consistent definition of a fund’s benchmark across all periods is difficult. Moreover, the active returns of a fund measured against its stated benchmark often contain common factor bets such as value, size or momentum that can distort the active returns coming purely from stock picking skills. For these reasons, we used factor models to determine the appropriate benchmark. We labeled as alpha or active return any returns that could not be explained by the factors of the model we used. Therefore, the choice of model and the factors that we included in the model were critical. Our objective was to assess the stock-picking skill of a manager, as a result all known “priced factors” should be included in our model and excluded from the manager’s alpha. “Priced factors” are factors for which empirical studies have demonstrated the existence of positive risk adjusted returns; namely: market, value, size and momentum. To assess a fund’s exposure to these factors, we used the same four-factor model as Carhart [1997]. In order to ensure that our results were not dependent on the model, we also used two alternative models that are based on similar factors but that use different techniques to assess the exposures. The first                                                               w  10 Kacperczyk et al. define as industry concentration as: portfolio  wimarket portfolio 2 (where wi is the weight of industry i in the i i portfolio and in the market portfolio). Cremers and Petajisto use active share, which, is the sum of the absolute deviations of the portfolio weights from the benchmark weights. Active Share  w i i portfolio  wibenchmark September, 2010 11
  • 12. alternative model is based on the characteristic based benchmarks developed by Daniel et al. [1997]. 11 The second alternative model is based on the 25 Fama-French portfolios sorted on value and size. (See appendix 2 for a more precise description of the models and the data). Exhibit 2 shows the average alpha, skill, diversification and number of securities per fund across each of the periods we examined. Alpha and skill are net of the funds’ expenses ratios. The decline in mutual fund alphas that we observed in this table was very important. The average mutual fund in our universe went from generating a 29 bps positive alpha in the first part of the a 90’s to a negative 1.3% alpha in the second part of the 90’s. This trend is consistent with the four-factor alphas reported by Kosowski et al. [2006] for similar periods and is also reported by Fama and French [2009]. Such variations in the average alpha and skill of mutual fund managers are surprising considering that since the 1990’s, the Investment Company Institute (ICI) has reported a decline in U.S. mutual fund expense ratios.12 The second interesting trend that we observed in Exhibit 2 was a general increase in the 13 number of positions per portfolio and therefore in the diversification of the funds. This increase in portfolio diversification among mutual fund managers is consistent with the inroads that modern portfolio theory made during the 80’s and 90’s among practitioners and the development of passive mutual funds. In addition, this period also witnessed a significant development of information technology solutions that drastically reduced the operational costs of running portfolios with a large number of positions. Exhibit 2: Number of Funds, Mean Alpha, Skill, Diversification and number of positions per portfolio for each Period. The benchmark of each portfolio is estimated with the Carhart [1997] model.                                                              11 See Daniel et al. [1997] and Wermers [2004] for more details on DGTW portfolio. The DGTW benchmarks are available via http://www.smith.umd.edu/faculty/rwermers/ftpsite/Dgtw/coverpage.htm. The Fama-French portfolio are available via: http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/data_library.html 12 See: Investment Company Institute Research Department Staff [2009] and Collins [2009] 13 Cremers and Petajisto [2009] report similar results using active share.  September, 2010 12
  • 13. Number of  Number of  Period  Funds Alpha SK DI Positions 1980‐1984 137 0.58% 0.007 36 71 1985‐1989 270 0.43% 0.004 45 84 1990‐1994 588 0.29% 0.001 62 96 1995‐1999 1519 ‐1.28% ‐0.013 65 125 2000‐2006 2378 ‐1.28% ‐0.008 70 148 1980‐2006 2798 ‐0.84% ‐0.007 63 135 We see two non-exclusive explanations for the decline in skill that we observed among equity mutual funds. First, mutual fund managers were victims of their own success. The net asset value of equity mutual funds as a percentage of the capitalization of the U.S. stock market increased from 3% to 40% between 1980 and 200814. If mutual fund managers are a representative sample of the equity market investors, Sharpe’s [1991] arithmetic of active management entails that as a whole, mutual fund managers should have a negative alpha roughly equal to the fees they charge. As the industry grows closer to representing the U.S. stock market, it is more difficult for the industry as a whole to outperform the market. The second explanation for this phenomenon is that the quality of U.S. Equity mutual funds has declined. The industry would have responded to the increase in demand for mutual funds that took place during the 80’s and 90’s by creating sub-par products. The market for asset management services, like the Lemons market described by Akerlof [1970], is characterized by an asymmetry of information.15 Since it is difficult for investors to distinguish a skilled from an unskilled manager, there is a large incentive for unskilled managers to flood the market and distribute low cost investment strategies that add no value while charging active management fees. This incentive is even greater when demand expands and new customers with less financial acumen enter the market. Under such circumstances, unskilled managers, or “closet indexers”, will want to take the minimum level of risk that allows them to charge active management fees. On the other hand, skilled managers have an incentive to take relatively more concentrated positions. Such situations should result in a positive                                                              14 To compute these percentages, we used net asset value of equity mutual funds reported in the 2009 Investment Company Fact Book (Investment Company Institute Research Department Staff [2009]) and the Wilshire 5000 index capitalization as a proxy for the capitalization of the U.S. stock market. 15 See Foster and Young [2008]   September, 2010 13
  • 14. skew in the distribution of alphas because skilled managers with concentrated portfolios will generate high alphas, while unskilled managers will generate moderate negative alphas. Under this hypothesis, the industry responded to an increasing demand for mutual funds by increasing its “lemon” production and crafting strategies with little information content and with the look and feel of effective active investment strategies. In order to assess this hypothesis, we examined the cross-sectional relation between skill and diversification by splitting our universe of mutual funds into quintiles of diversification and compared the skill of the funds located in each quintile. Exhibit 3: Alpha and Skill by Quintiles of Diversification The benchmark of each portfolio is estimated with the Carhart [1997] model. Skill by Diversification(DI) Quintile (1980‐2006) Quintile 1:   Quintile 5:  Low DI Quintile 2 Quintile 3 Quintile 4 High DI Mean  0.004 ‐0.007 ‐0.011 ‐0.011 ‐0.011 T‐stat (Mean Skill) 2.02 ‐6.34 ‐10.77 ‐11.98 ‐14.50 Skill Difference : Quintile 1 ‐ Quintile 2,3,4 or 5 0.012 0.016 0.015 0.015 T‐stat (Skill Difference) 4.78 6.45 6.50 6.51 Standard Deviation 0.05 0.03 0.02 0.02 0.02 Skewness 0.97 ‐0.21 0.15 ‐0.51 ‐0.62 Kurtosis 7.06 5.03 5.17 4.46 4.98 Number of Observations  560 559 560 559 560 In Exhibit 3, we observe that funds located in the first diversification quintile did exhibit significantly more skill than any of the other quintiles. On average, the skill of these funds was greater than zero while the skill in all the other quintiles of the distribution was significantly less than zero. All the differences in skill between quintile 1 and each of the four other quintiles are statistically significant. Exhibit 3 also indicates a positive skew in the distribution of the skill of low diversification portfolio managers. This fact indicates that our result could be explained by survivorship bias. Less diversification implies more risk. Since we required at least 36 months of returns to include a fund in our analysis, it is possible that the low diversification funds that severely underperformed rapidly lost their clients and did not survive long enough to be included in our analysis. Note that the positive skew in the distribution of alpha can be explained by factors other than survivorship bias. As we observed earlier, the presence of closet indexers or “lemons” in the mutual fund market is consistent with such distribution of alphas. September, 2010 14
  • 15. In order to test the impact of a possible survivorship bias on our results, we created an artificial bias against the top performing funds by eliminating funds in the right tail of the alpha distribution in order to have a symmetric distribution. We removed from our analysis all funds whose alpha was greater than the absolute value of the first percentile of the alpha distribution. After removing these funds, the skew of the distribution became slightly negative; however, the skill difference between the first quintile of managers and the rest of the universe remained strongly significant (see top-panel of exhibit 4). In order to further test the robustness of our results, we designed a more conservative artificial survivorship bias, where we removed all funds with alpha greater than the absolute value of the fifth percentile of the alpha distribution. Under this definition of the artificial survivorship bias, we eliminated from our sample all the funds with annualized alpha greater than 6.7% per annum. Nevertheless, the bottom panel of exhibit 4 shows that low diversification funds still exhibited significantly higher skill under both definitions of the artificial survivorship bias. Hence, the relationship that we observed between skill and diversification cannot be explained away by survivorship bias. Exhibit 4: Alpha and Skill by Diversification Quintiles From 1980 to 2006 Excluding top Performing Funds Out-performing funds are funds with an alpha greater than the absolute value of the first or fifth percentile of the alpha distribution. The benchmark of each portfolio is estimated with the Carhart model. Skill by Diversification(DI) Quintile (1980‐2006) Excluding Top‐ Performing Funds  Quintile 1:   Quintile 5:  Low DI Quintile 2 Quintile 3 Quintile 4 High DI Mean  ‐0.001 ‐0.009 ‐0.011 ‐0.011 ‐0.010 Absolute Value of 1st  T‐stat (Mean Skill) ‐0.48 ‐7.55 ‐11.27 ‐12.40 ‐14.27 Skill Difference : Quintile 1 ‐ Quintile 2,3,4 or 5 0.008 0.011 0.010 0.010 Percentile Alpha Alpha less than  T‐stat (Skill Difference) 3.61 5.10 5.18 4.94 Standard Deviation 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.02 0.02 Skewness ‐0.04 ‐0.46 ‐0.18 ‐0.54 ‐0.63 Kurtosis 5.35 4.62 3.97 4.43 5.00 Number of Observations  554 554 554 554 554 Mean  ‐0.007 ‐0.01 ‐0.012 ‐0.011 ‐0.011 Absolute Value of 5th  T‐stat (Mean Skill) ‐4.08 ‐9.28 ‐11.62 ‐12.62 ‐14.53 Skill Difference : Quintile 1 ‐ Quintile 2,3,4 or 5 0.003 0.005 0.005 0.004 Percentile Alpha Alpha less than  T‐stat (Skill Difference) 1.80 2.73 2.58 2.31 Standard Deviation 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.02 0.02 Skewness ‐0.59 ‐0.60 ‐0.27 ‐0.55 ‐0.84 Kurtosis 5.53 4.31 3.85 4.42 4.49 Number of Observations  543 542 543 542 543 September, 2010 15
  • 16. The relation between skill and diversification also held across the three different types of models that we used to define the alpha for the 1980-2006 period. Exhibit 5 also shows strongly significant results if we use the characteristic based benchmarks or the 25 Fama-French portfolios to establish the alpha of each fund. However, the relationship between skill and diversification was not consistent across periods. Breaking up the 1980-2006 periods into 5 distinct sub-periods, we did not find that low diversification funds outperformed in each sub-period (see exhibit 5). We did not find any significant relation between diversification and skill during the eighties and the early nineties. Exhibit 5: Relation between Skill and Diversification across periods and models For each period and each model, we show the mean of the t-stats for the differences in skill between quintile one and quintiles two to five (Mean t-stat). We also show the smallest of the four t-stats (Min t-stat). For the Carhart model in the period 1980- 2006, we can read from table 3 that the four t-stats are 4.78, 6.45, 6.50 and 6.51. The mean of these four t-stats: 6.06 and minimum: 4.78 are displayed in the top left cell of table 5. FF-25 denotes the results that we obtained with the 25 Fama-French portfolios, DGTW indicate that we used the characteristic based benchmarks of Daniel et al. [1997] 1980        2000        1995        1990        1985        1980        to          to          to          to          to          to          Periods:   2006 2006 1999 1994 1989 1984 Mean t‐stat 6.06 7.46 2.11 ‐0.40 0.68 ‐0.28 Carhart  Min t‐stat  4.78 6.90 1.84 ‐0.64 0.07 ‐0.71 Mean t‐stat 3.59 2.23 4.08 0.86 ‐0.57 ‐1.52 DGTW Min t‐stat  1.95 1.78 2.54 0.50 ‐2.26 ‐1.98 Mean t‐stat 4.29 3.15 5.33 0.91 1.15 ‐1.03 FF‐25 Min t‐stat  3.66 1.75 4.50 0.04 0.20 ‐1.25 Number of Observations per Quintile 559.6 475.6 303.8 117.6 54 27.6 Since we could not find a significant relation between diversification and skill in every sub-period, we found it difficult to conclude that concentrated managers had an intrinsic advantage over less concentrated managers. Instead, the result of this study is better interpreted using Lo’s [2004] Adaptative Market Hypothesis. The ability of U.S. mutual funds to beat the market evolved through time under the influence of the structure of the U.S. market for mutual funds. Our interpretation of these results is based on two elements. First, concentration among mutual fund managers has decreased since the 80’s. Second, our analysis shows that since the mid-90’s, skill was more likely to be found in more concentrated portfolios. These two points taken together indicated that as the demand for mutual funds increased, the industry responded by producing funds with higher diversification but lower information content, also known as “closet-indexers.” As a result, the average September, 2010 16
  • 17. skill and alpha of U.S. equity mutual funds decreased. In most industries, increases in demand are met by increases in price; however, no such price increase took place in the asset management industry during the 90’s.16 We infer from our data that the asset management industry took advantage of this increase in demand by cutting the information content of its products while leaving its management fees unchanged. Conclusion The Fundamental Law of Active Management played a very important role in the development of quantitative asset management. The application of this law was designed by quantitative investment managers for quantitative investment managers, and is difficult to apply to other types of processes. However, the result of the Fundamental Law of Active Management applies to all investment managers. The Empirical Law of Asset Management presented in this paper seeks to generalize and extend this tool to a wider range of portfolios while conserving the key insights that made this concept a success. The application of this analytical framework to U.S. equity mutual funds reveals a general decline in skill. We found two explanations for this decrease in skill. Firstly, the mutual fund industry was a victim of its own success, as mutual funds represent a greater share of the market capitalization. It is now close to impossible for the industry as a whole to outperform the market. Secondly, the decrease in skill was accompanied by an increase in diversification. Since the mid-90’s, we also observe an inverse relationship between skill and diversification. We suggest that the increase in diversification does reflect a decrease in the quality of the information content of U.S. mutual funds.                                                              16 See: Investment Company Institute Research Department Staff [2009] September, 2010 17
  • 18. References: Akerlof, George. “The Market for "Lemons": Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 84, No. 3 (1970), pp. 488-500. Beckers, Stan, G. Vaughan. “Small is Beautiful.” Journal of Portfolio Management, Vol. 27, No. 4 (2001), pp. 9-17. Berk, Jonathan, R. Green. “Mutual Fund Flows and Performance in Rational Markets.” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 112, No. 6 (2004), pp. 1269-1295. Buckle, David. “How to calculate breadth: An evolution of the Fundamental Law of Active Management.” Journal of Asset Management, Vol. 4, No. 6 (2004), pp. 393-405. Daniel, Kent, M. Grinblatt, S. Titman and R. Wermers. “Measuring Mutual Fund Performance with Characteristic Based Benchmarks.” The Journal of Finance, Vol. 52, No. 3 (1997), pp. 1035-1058. Carhart, Mark M. “On Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance.” The Journal of Finance, Vol. 52, No. 1 (1997), pp. 57-82. Chen, Joseph, H. Hong, M. Huang and J. Kubik. “Does Fund Size Erode Mutual Fund Performance? The Role of Liquidity and Organization.” The American Economic Review, Vol. 94, No. 5 (2004), pp. 1276- 1302. Clarke, Roger, H. de Silva, S. Thorley. “Portfolio Constraints and the Fundamental Law of Active Management.” Financial Analysts Journal, September/October 2002, Vol. 58, No. 5 (2002), pp. 48-66. “The Fundamental Law of Active Portfolio Management.” Journal of Investment Management, Vol. 4, No. 3 (2006), pp. 54–72. Collins, Sean. “Trends in the Fees and Expenses of Mutual Funds, 2008.” Investment Company Institute Research Fundamentals, Vol. 18, No. 3 (April 2009) Cremers, Martjin, A. Petajisto “How Active is Your Fund Manager? A New Measure that Predicts Performance.” Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 22, No. 9 (September 2009), pp. 3329-3365. Foster, Dean, P. Young. “The Hedge Fund Game: Incentives, Excess Returns, and Performance Mimics.” University of Oxford, Discussion Paper Series (2008). Grinold, Richard C. “The Fundamental Law of Active Management.” The Journal of Portfolio Management, Vol. 15, No. 3 (Spring 1989), pp. 30-37. Grinold, Richard C., R. Kahn. Active Portfolio Management: A Quantitative Approach for Producing Superior Returns and Controlling Risk, 2nd ed. McGraw-Hill, 1999. Investment Company Institute Research Department Staff, “2009 Investment Company Fact Book”, 49th Edition, (2009). Kacperczyk, Marcin T., C. Sialm, L. Zheng. “On Industry concentration of Actively Managed Equity Mutual Funds.” The Journal of Finance, 60 (2005), pp. 1983-2012. Kacperczyk, Marcin T., C. Sialm, L. Zheng. “Industry Concentration and Mutual Fund Performance.” Journal of Investment Management, Vol. 5, No. 1 (2007) Kosowski, Robert, A. Timmermann, R. Wermers, A. White. “Can Mutual fund “Stars” Really Pick Stocks? New Evidence from a Bootstrap Analysis.” Journal of Finance, Vol. 51, No. 6 (2006), pp. 2551-2595. September, 2010 18
  • 19. Fama, Eugene, K. French. “Luck versus Skill in the Cross Section of Mutual Fund Alpha Estimates.” working paper (2009) Lo, Andrew. “Risk management for hedge funds: introduction and overview.” Financial Analysts Journal, Vol. 57, No. 6 (November/December 2001), pp.16-33. “The Adaptive Markets Hypothesis: Market Efficiency from an Evolutionary Perspective.” Journal of Portfolio Management, 30 (2004), pp. 15-29. “Where Do Alphas Come From?: A New Measure of the Value of Active Investment Management.” Journal of Investment Management, forthcoming. Sharpe, William. “The Arithmetic of Active Management” Financial Analysts Journal, Vol. 47, No. 1 (January/February 1991), pp. 7-9. Shleifer, Andrei, R. Vishny. “The Limits of Arbitrage.” The Journal of Finance, Vol. 52, No. 1 (1997), pp. 35-55. Pollet, Joshua, M. Wilson. “How Does Size Affect Fund Behavior?” working paper (2007). Van Nieuwerburgh, Stijn, L. Veldkamp. “Information Acquisition and Under-Diversification.” working paper (2008). Wermers, Russ. “Are Mutual Fund Shareholders Compensated for Active Management "Bets"?” working paper (2003). “Is Money Really 'Smart'? New Evidence on the Relation Between Mutual Fund Flows, Manager Behavior, and Performance Persistence.” working paper (2004). September, 2010 19
  • 20. Appendix 1: derivation of the Empirical Law of Active Management wi is the weight of security i in the portfolio w is the vector of all the securities weights in the portfolio.  is the covariance matrix of the securities’ active return. If V is a classic covariance matrix of assets returns of size (n x n), and B is a (n x n) matrix which contains n times the (n x1) vector of benchmark weights and I is the identity matrix then  can be obtained in the following way:   ( I  B)'V ( I  B) . 17 The active variance of the portfolio ( w' w ) can be decomposed into the risk of the portfolio if all securities were perfectly correlated and a second term which represents the benefits from diversification. w' w   wi2 i2   wi w j  i j  i , j i i j i w' w   w    wi w j  i j (1   i , j  1) 2 i i 2 i i j i 2   w' w    wi i    wi w j  i j (1   i , j )  i  i j i We separated the risk of the portfolio into two parts: First, the average volatility, which is the risk if all positions were perfectly correlated. And second, the diversification benefits, which is the decrease in risk due to positions in the portfolio being less than perfectly correlated. Let’s note the average risk of a position in the portfolio as:                                                              17 The I  B matrix contains n columns of active weights for n portfolios that are fully invested in one and only one asset: 1 0 ... 0  w1b w1b ... w1b  0  b b 1 ... 0  w2   b w2 ... w2  I B   w1active w2 ... wn active active ... ... ... ...  ... ... ... ...     b b 0 0 ... 1  wn  wn ... wn  b  September, 2010 20
  • 21.    wi i i wi i Let’s note risk weights: i  with these notations the active variance of a portfolio is:  2   w' w     i     2 i j (  i , j  1)  i  i j i We can re-write the active variance of the portfolio in the following way:   w' w   2   2    i  j  i , j    i  j     i j i i j i  Or:   w' w   2 1    i  j  i , j    i  j     i j i i j i  The term    i j i i j  i , j    i j can be broken down into two components: i j i - the product of the risk weights =     i j i i j (Equation 1) - risk weighted correlation =    i j i i j i, j (Equation 2) We can rewrite equation 1 as:            1    i j i i j i i j i j i i i which can be expressed in function of the variance of the risk weights: 2 1 1  i j   i  i2   i    i   i j i i i n n 2  1   1 1 1 i i j  1    n 2     i  n    2 n  i  n  i j i   i   i   September, 2010 21
  • 22. 2 1  1 i  i j  1  n     i  n  i j i   n 1    i j i i j  n  n * Variance(i ) Hence the concentration of the risk weights is a direct function of the variance of the risk weights: n 1    i  j  nVar ( i )  i j i n The higher the dispersion of the risk weights (that is the dispersion of portfolio weights and volatilities), the higher the active risk of the portfolio. The second element of this diversification term is the correlations among the positions of the portfolio (equation 2).    i j i i j  i, j   i   j  i, j i j i We note  i the average correlation of asset i with the other assets in the portfolio, weighted by the 18 risk-weight of each asset in the portfolio.  i    j  i , j hence we obtain:   i j  i , j    i  i ~ j i i j i i We call this quantity the risk weighted correlation:           i i i i j i i j i, j If we put everything back together:  n2  1 1  w' w   2 1    nVar ( )      2     nVar ( )    n  n                                                               18 Note that the sum of the risk-weights excluding asset i does not add-up to one. The correct weighted average should be: i   j i , j The correlation term becomes:   (1   )  i i i   j  i (1  i ) i September, 2010 22
  • 23. The diversification factor of the portfolio is defined as: 1 DI  1 ~    nVar ( i ) n Appendix 2: The mutual funds quarterly holdings were obtained from the Thomson-Reuters mutual fund database. The funds monthly returns were gathered from the CRSP mutual fund database and the securities’ returns were obtained from the CRSP U.S. Stock database. We used the MF Link mapping developed by Russ Wermers to map funds in the Thomson-Reuters database to funds in the CRSP database. We examined separately 6 periods: 1980-1984, 1985-1989, 1990-1994, 1995-1999, 2000-2006 and 1980- 2006. To be included in the analysis of a period a fund should have at least 36 months of returns during that period. For each period, we used the following steps to compute the diversification and skill factors. First we computed the return of each fund by taking the asset-weighted average return of all share-classes. If a share-class asset value was missing on a given date, we took the equal-weighted average return of all the share classes. Second, we assessed the fund benchmark using each of the following three pricing models: the four- factor model used by Carhart [1997] (henceforth: “Carhart”); a second pricing model based on the Daniel, Grinblatt, Titman and Wermers characteristic based benchmarks (“DGTW”); and a third pricing model based on the 25 Fama-French portfolios sorted on Value and Size (“FF-25”). 19 For the Carhart model, we performed a regression of the fund returns on the four factors of the model (market, value, size and momentum). The exposure to the four factors resulting from this regression defined the benchmark of the fund. As a result, the active return of the fund was equal to the alpha of the fund computed with the Carhart model.                                                              19 See Daniel et al. [1997] and Wermers [2004] for more details on DGTW portfolio. The DGTW benchmarks are available via http://www.smith.umd.edu/faculty/rwermers/ftpsite/Dgtw/coverpage.htm. The Fama-French portfolio are available via: http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/data_library.html September, 2010 23
  • 24. For DGTW, we performed a regression of the fund returns on the market portfolio and one of the 125 characteristic based benchmarks and the market factor. The DGTW benchmarks are the result of a sort of U.S. stocks on value, size and momentum exposures. We choose a unique DGTW benchmark which, when combined with the market portfolio, maximizes the variance explained by the regression. The market portfolio that we used with each of these models was the value-weighted return on all NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ stocks (from CRSP), minus the one-month Treasury bill rate. We followed the same procedure for the FF-25 portfolios. For each period we computed the historical active volatility of each asset in each fund using the securities monthly returns. Asset active volatility is the standard deviation of the difference between the asset returns and the benchmark returns. If a security does not have at least 24 months of returns, we set its active volatility to the equal weighted average volatility of the fund’s assets with more than 24 months of returns. Every quarter, we compute the mean weighted volatility. The fund mean weighted volatility for a period is the mean of each of the quarterly mean weighted volatility during that period. For a quarterly observation of the portfolio to be included in our analysis, we required that at least 75% of the assets in the portfolio be recognized in the CRSP U.S. Stock database. For a fund to be included in the analysis of a period, we required at least 8 valid quarters. In addition, we excluded from the analysis, funds that had an average across all quarters of a period more than 5% of assets not recognized in the CRSP U.S. Stock database. We excluded funds that, on average across all quarters of a given period, had fewer than 10 positions, or less than 15 million dollars of asset under management. Using the three models, we computed alpha (active return) and residual risk (active risk) during each of the periods we analyzed. We then computed the weighted mean asset volatility of each portfolio using the monthly historical return of each asset in the fund. Finally, we took the mean of these quarterly volatilities across the entire period to obtain a proxy for the fund asset weighted volatility (  ) for the period and used the following decomposition to compute the fund’s skill and diversification. September, 2010 24
  • 25.   DI= and SK    Model Choices While the Carhart model is the standard pricing model used in the literature, the findings of Cremers and Petajisto [2009] raised questions about the suitability of this model to establish a pertinent performance benchmark. Unlike Cremers and Patajisto, we obtained strongly significant results with the Carhart model. However, we still wanted to ensure that our results were not dependent on the type of model we were using, so we recomputed our results with two alternative models. The DGTW benchmarks offer a very granular classification of U.S. stocks into benchmarks based on their value, size and momentum characteristics. These DGTW benchmarks have fewer stocks than a typical benchmark and therefore more idiosyncratic risk. We also used a coarser asset classification framework: the 25 Fama-French value and size sorted portfolios. The disadvantage of the Fama-French portfolio is that we did not account for the funds’ momentum exposure. Using these three models, we computed alpha (or active return), residual risk (or active risk), skill and diversification of each portfolio during each of the periods we analyzed. In theory, we should also have excluded from the active returns the returns due all non-priced factors to which the funds are systematically exposed. However, there is an infinite set of non-priced factors that could be included in the benchmark definition. Therefore, using non-priced factors was not practical. Since exposures are computed based on the historical co-movement of the fund’s returns and the factor returns, we would have picked up spurious relations between the funds’ returns and the factors if we used a larger number of non-priced factors. As a result, we would have obtained a very narrow definition of the fund’s alpha. September, 2010 25